Paul Collier - Wars, Guns, and Votes

Home > Other > Paul Collier - Wars, Guns, and Votes > Page 15
Paul Collier - Wars, Guns, and Votes Page 15

by Democracy in Dangerous Places (pdf)


  teered to build a data set on the price of Kalashnikovs on the infor-

  mal market around the world, country by country and year by year.

  This took real ingenuity, but he had it. After seven months he had

  three hundred observations, which was enough for statistical analy-

  sis. We were in business. Even a cursory look at the numbers showed

  interesting patterns: a secondhand Kalashnikov was only about half

  as expensive in Africa as in the rest of the world. So our research

  shaped itself around this finding: why were Kalashnikovs so much

  cheaper in Africa than elsewhere, and did it matter? Phil faced an

  examination on his work: generally, economics departments are not

  particularly impressed by the importance of a question; they are con-

  cerned about whether the student has applied the latest techniques

  to the highest possible standards. Somehow, despite being the first

  Oxford student in half a century to go from zero rowing experi-

  ence to being selected for the university’s team, and spending seven

  months on data gathering, Phil also managed to gain a distinction

  grade on his thesis: you can be reasonably confident that his results

  are defensible.

  So why are secondhand Kalashnikovs cheap in Africa? The an-

  swer is that the key source is leakage from government armies. Gov-

  ernment soldiers are usually very badly paid, and so they are tempted

  to sell their guns or steal from stockpiles. Government armies buy

  Kalashnikovs most vigorously when they are fighting a rebellion. So

  the guns are officially imported into Africa, stolen, and so become

  illegal, but cannot easily be re-exported to the markets in which sec-

  ondhand Kalashnikovs fetch a high price. That is because to export

  the guns out of Africa they have to be imported into countries that

  generally have sufficiently good border controls to make it difficult.

  But the guns do not just stay in the country whose government first

  imported them to Africa. Africa’s internal borders are highly po-

  rous, and so the cheap guns slosh around the continent going to

  116

  WARS, GUNS, AND VOTES

  where there is currently demand: which means wherever there is a

  war. The next question was “Does it matter?” By this Phil meant

  whether cheap guns increased the risk of rebellion. According to

  simple economic theory it ought to do so: cheap guns should make

  rebellion easier and so more likely, or, stated slightly differently,

  small rebel groups would tend to buy more guns as a result of their

  being cheap, and so be more likely to scale up their violence to the

  point at which it met the definition of a civil war. I have to admit

  that I thought that this was a pretty demanding question to ask of

  the data. In the event, Phil found a significant effect: cheap guns

  increased the risk of civil war. When Phil went back to Australia he

  generously deposited all his data with the Peace Research Institute,

  Oslo, where it sits waiting for some other enterprising student to

  update and expand it.

  One implication of Phil’s work is that dangerous countries

  make for dangerous regions. Another is that if Africa’s internal bor-

  ders are porous, the way to curtail armaments reaching the current

  danger points is to curtail arms flows to the entire region. There

  are two ways of going about such curtailment, neither easy. One is

  to address the inadvertent leakage of aid into the purchase of ar-

  maments: squeezing the finance for armaments should reduce their

  inflow. The other is to attempt to impose quantitative restrictions

  on the trade flows.

  Each of these approaches might seem impertinent: other regions

  buy plenty of armaments, why shouldn’t Africa? Before Africans

  and sympathizers put on the comfortable clothes of indignation,

  step back for a moment and think of Africa’s own interest. Quite

  manifestly, Africa no longer faces a military threat external to the

  region: all its threats are internal, either threats between neighbors

  or fears of rebellion. Threats from neighbors place governments in a

  prisoner’s dilemma. Although each country’s increase in its military

  spending makes it feel more secure, it does so by making its neigh-

  bors feel less secure. As I discussed, the neighbors respond to this

  Guns

  117

  by increasing their own military spending. Arms races in Lilliput

  are a menace for the region as a whole. Further, recall that military

  spending is higher when countries are small. Africa is divided into

  fifty-four countries, despite having a total population far less than

  that of India. And so the waste that comes from military spending is

  more of a problem in Africa than in regions with fewer countries.

  The solution to a prisoner’s dilemma is cooperation. Africa

  needs collective action to curtail its arms spending. But the problem

  with cooperation is enforcement: each government has an individ-

  ual interest in encouraging its neighbors to coordinate reductions

  in their military spending while not doing so itself. There are vari-

  ous ways of securing cooperation, but the most straightforward is

  to persuade a neutral policeman to enforce it. The policeman could

  be the donors limiting leakage from aid, or it could be the United

  Nations imposing effective embargoes on arms exports. But in one

  shape or form Africa should be searching for a policeman. As I ex-

  plained, the donors have recently reshaped aid allocations so that

  it is even more difficult to prevent leakages. So how about direct

  restrictions on arms exports?

  I f a i d i s i na dv e rt e n t ly f i na n c i n g arms purchases, and if cheap guns make civil war more likely, one possible remedy might

  be to limit the flow of armaments into dangerous places. Fortu-

  nately, the countries most at risk of civil war are not sufficiently in-

  dustrialized to have an arms industry, so that curtailing the trade

  might indeed limit the availability of guns. In recent years sufficient

  popular pressure has built up behind this idea that from time to time

  it is implemented. For example, during the standoff in Cote d’Ivoire

  between the government in the south and a rebel group in the north,

  the United Nations placed an embargo on arms shipments to either

  side. Are such arms embargoes effective? The work I am going to

  describe is by Stefano DellaVigna and Eliana La Ferrara.

  118

  WARS, GUNS, AND VOTES

  They reasoned that if anybody knew what was really going on,

  it was the people who were investing their money in companies that

  manufactured armaments. Of course, not everyone who buys shares

  in a company knows much about how it is performing. But it only

  needs a few people to take the time and energy to find out in order

  for the share price to be affected: if they discover that the company

  is being hurt by an embargo, they will sell their shares and the price

  of the stock will fall. Using this reasoning DellaVigna and La Fer-

  rara got information on which armaments companies were export-

  ing to the country prior
to the embargo. They then checked what

  the announcement of the embargo did to the subsequent price of

  the stocks.

  What they found must at first have seemed confusing: although

  the stock prices duly fell for some companies, for others prices ac-

  tually went up. Was this just noise: random movements in stock

  prices? It turned out that it was not random. The stock prices of

  armaments companies based in the OECD—that is, the developed

  countries—fell significantly as a result of an embargo. But the stock

  prices of armaments companies based outside the OECD rose. They

  realized that the most likely explanation for this was that these latter

  companies were breaking the embargo and, in the process, profiting

  from the absence of competition from the OECD companies.

  They concluded from that analysis not that arms embargoes

  cannot work, but that there is a simple method of policing them

  more effectively. Suspicions should be raised if an embargoed com-

  pany’s stock price rises as a result of the embargo. It is a simple idea

  with a lot of potential that demonstrates the payoff to statistical re-

  search.

  O n e k e y c o n c l u s i o n f ro m a l l this is that military spending is likely to be excessive, driven up in an arms race spiral, and so be a

  regional public bad. Collectively, the countries of the bottom billion

  Guns

  119

  are spending around $9 billion on the military, of which up to 40 per-

  cent is being financed by donors. Similarly, in regions where borders

  are porous, a profusion of guns purchased by the government of one

  country gradually seem to leak onto the informal markets of neigh-

  boring countries. These cheap guns on informal markets increase

  the risk of civil war. The final menace is that in post-conflict societ-

  ies, which are usually big military spenders, the military is counter-

  productive, provoking the very risk that it is meant to deter.

  Not only is military spending excessive but aid is paying for it.

  If the international community is minded to put matters right it has

  two potential strategies: quantitative restrictions on arms purchases

  or an incentive through linking aid allocations to the chosen level of

  military spending. Arms embargoes can be made to work despite

  their past lack of success. Guns are fueling the fire of political vio-

  lence, and there is a need for them to be curbed.

  C h a p t e r 5

  WA R S : T H E P O L I T I C A L

  E C O N O M Y O F D E S T R U C T I O N

  Why are some places prone to war? Iraq has

  deeply confused how people think about twenty-

  first-century war. The war in Iraq is not a guide to

  the future; it is a rerun of a phase in world history that is essentially

  over. Iraq started with an international invasion. So did the two world

  wars, Napoleon’s wars, the Crimean War, the Franco-Prussian War,

  and the other great set pieces of military history. In the twenty-first

  century international invasions are going to be infrequent. The wars

  that will fill our television screens this century will be civil wars, not

  international wars. Of course, there were civil wars in the nineteenth

  century as well as invasions, but even the civil wars of the nineteenth

  century are a hopeless guide to what warfare will be like. The major

  civil war of the nineteenth century was the American Civil War. This

  was in form, if not in law, an international war: one alliance of states

  fought another alliance of states, each with its own recognized terri-

  tory, government, and army. It’s history.

  Future civil wars will take the form of a government pitted

  against a private extralegal military grouping. They will variously

  be called rebels, terrorists, freedom fighters, or gangsters, but their

  essential characteristic will be the same. These wars will also be a

  122

  WARS, GUNS, AND VOTES

  throwback, but to a very different period of history: the time before

  nation-states cohered.

  To rephrase the question, why are some countries more at risk

  of civil war than others? If we could answer this question we might

  be able to do something about it: some of the factors that elevate the

  risk of civil war might be things that could readily be put right. I

  think I have the answers to this question, although I am not fully

  sure of them, even after studying the causes of civil wars for some

  years. My approach is statistical: I take over all the countries in the

  world for as long a period as possible and try to find what accounts

  for why civil wars break out in some places at some times but not in

  other places at other times: why some places are dangerous.

  The core of my approach is to try to predict whether a country

  has an outbreak of civil war on the basis of its characteristics prior

  to the war. There are many pitfalls in this approach, but the key

  problem is the lack of data. Records of the civil wars themselves are

  not the problem. Astonishingly, a small team at the University of

  Michigan, the university that pioneered the quantitative analysis of

  political phenomena, has built a record of all the world’s civil wars

  since 1815. There is even now a rival list built up in Scandinavia. But

  for most of this period there are too little other data to match against

  these outbreaks of civil war to try to explain them: for example, for

  most countries reasonable economic data do not exist prior to 1960.

  Even if the data were available, prior to 1960, for many years, virtu-

  ally all the low-income world was in empires that kept the lid on

  internal conflict. The period prior to empires would probably be re-

  vealing, but there are as yet too few hard numbers for my approach

  to be feasible. Even for the period post-1960 the countries that are

  most likely to have a civil war also tend to be those least likely to

  have adequate data on other characteristics: they are the dots and

  blanks in the global tables produced by the international organiza-

  tions. Fortunately, time has been on my side.

  When Anke and I first tried the approach, in the late 1990s,

  Wars

  123

  we could muster only twenty-three civil wars to explain. This was

  pretty close to being hopeless. By the time of our next effort, pub-

  lished in 2004, we were up to fifty-three civil wars and around

  550 episodes during which a civil war could have occurred. This

  was an improvement but it was still far from ideal. In our most

  recent work we have been joined by Dominic Rohner, and time

  has helped in three distinct ways. The most obvious way is that

  there has been more time in which civil wars have occurred, or

  more encouragingly, might have occurred but didn’t. Anke and

  I work in five-year episodes, and whereas our previous analysis

  took the story only up to the end of 1999, we are now able to take

  it up to the end of 2004. Indeed, this is a very strategic additional

  five years because it was the period of a major effort by the inter-

  national community to settle wars, and so we can test whether it

&n
bsp; also reduced the incidence of outbreaks. But time has helped us by

  more than just this. Scholars have been hyperactive in quantifying

  phenomena that were not previously measured, and at filling in

  the gaps in previous estimates, so that our data for the past are now

  much nearer to being complete.

  The third way in which time has helped is the embarrassing

  one: we have got better at doing the work. We realized that we could

  use a fancy statistical program that fills in the blanks of missing data

  by randomly assigning a range of different numbers. I had always

  been resistant to using make-believe numbers, but the advantage of

  this approach was that it filled in each missing number with several

  different possibilities, one at a time. Using these numbers in turn,

  you could then see how robust the results were to the possibility that

  the missing number would have taken these values. We used this

  to check on our core results derived only from those numbers that

  were genuine.

  Another way in which we got smarter was better to control for

  reverse causality or common causality, the current obsession in pro-

  fessional economics. Take one of our core results, that low-income

  124

  WARS, GUNS, AND VOTES

  countries are more likely to have outbreaks of civil war. Is this more

  than just an association between low income and civil war: the two

  phenomena tending to occur together but the first not causing the

  second? The step from association to causality is tricky, and I will try

  to spell out why. A rudimentary way of getting from association to

  causality is the sequence in which events happen. If the low income

  occurs before the outbreak of war, then this suggests that causality

  runs from income to war. But is this enough? There are three ways

  in which this step from association to causality could be mistaken.

  One is that the civil war could be anticipated. If you know that

  you are living in a country at risk of violent conflict, then you are

  less likely to invest. And so the country will be tend to be poor due

  to the war even prior to the outbreak of the war. But low income

  has not caused the war; instead the prospect of the war has caused

  low income. Another is that the country might have some charac-

  teristic not included in our analysis that keeps causing civil wars: for

 

‹ Prev