The Economics of Artificial Intelligence

Home > Other > The Economics of Artificial Intelligence > Page 82
The Economics of Artificial Intelligence Page 82

by Ajay Agrawal


  market, a weakening dollar might repatriate manufacturing jobs. At the high

  end of the market, skilled US workers will for the fi rst time be exposed to

  competition from a low- wage country. In isolation, this would reduce one

  dimension of domestic US inequality.

  If the Chinese market becomes open to US technology giants (and vice

  versa), both the Melitz (2003) model and the Oberfi eld (2018) model of trade

  predict that the giants will grow even larger. In the context in which these

  companies have already absorbed one- fi fth of US value added, and may

  have contributed to US top- end inequality, the impact of international trade

  in further growing these impacts may increase top- end inequality.

  26. https:// obamawhitehouse.archives .gov/ sites/ default/ fi les/ omb/ IPEC/ admin_strategy _on_mitigating_the_theft_of_u.s._trade_secrets .pdf.

  Artifi cial Intelligence and International Trade 489

  19.6 Conclusion

  How will artifi cial intelligence aff ect the pattern of trade? How does it

  make us think diff erently about trade policy? In this article we have tried to

  highlight some key points.

  First, the nature of the technology suggests that economies of scale and

  scope will be important. Furthermore, as a knowledge- intensive industry,

  knowledge externalities are likely to be important. Prior literature on other

  industries suggests that such externalities are often local, but more evidence

  is needed. Second, the trade models that are likely to be most useful in

  understanding the impact of AI are those that account for these points,

  specifi cally, scale, knowledge creation, and the geography of knowledge dif-

  fusion. These models suggest that whether AI- focused trade policies (or

  AI- focused investments in clusters) are optimal will depend very much on

  the presence of scale and the absence of rapid international knowledge diff u-

  sion. Third, we discussed whether and how regulation might be used to favor

  domestic industry. We highlighted that privacy policy that targets consumer

  protection is unlike many other regulations in that it is likely to hamstring

  domestic fi rms, even relative to foreign ones. So, rather than focusing trade

  discussions on how privacy policy might be used as a disguised restriction

  on trade, such discussions should emphasize regulatory harmonization so

  as to avoid a race to the bottom. In contrast, several other policies may be

  used to favor domestic fi rms including data localization rules, limited access

  to government data, industry regulations such as those around the use of

  drones, and forced access to source code.

  Generally, this is an exciting new area for trade research and policy. There

  is still much to learn before we have a comprehensive understanding of these

  questions.

  References

  Acquisti, Alessandro, Curtis Taylor, and Liad Wagman. 2016. “The Economics of

  Privacy.” Journal of Economic Literature 54 (2): 442– 92.

  Aghion, Philippe, Antonin Bergeaud, Matthieu Lequien, and Marc Melitz. 2017.

  “The Impact of Exports on Innovation: Theory and Evidence.” Working paper,

  Harvard University.

  Aghion, Philippe, Nick Bloom, Richard Blundell, Rachel Griffi

  th, and Peter Howitt.

  2005. “Competition and Innovation: An Inverted- U Relationship.” Quarterly

  Journal of Economics 120 (2): 701– 28.

  Aghion, Philippe, Christopher Harris, Peter Howitt, and John Vickers. 2001. “Com-

  petition, Imitation and Growth with Step- by- Step Innovation.” Review of Eco-

  nomic Studies 68 (3): 467– 92.

  490 Avi Goldfarb and Daniel Trefl er

  Aghion, Philippe, and Peter Howitt. 2009. The Economics of Growth. Cambridge,

  MA: MIT Press.

  Agrawal, Ajay, Joshua Gans, and Avi Goldfarb. 2018. Prediction Machines: The

  Simple Economics of Artifi cial Intelligence. Boston, MA: Harvard Business Re-

  view Press.

  Autor, David, David Dorn, Lawrence F. Katz, Christina Patterson, and John Van

  Reenen. 2017. “Concentrating on the Fall of the Labor Share.” NBER Working

  Paper no. 23108, Cambridge, MA.

  Azoulay, Pierre, Joshua S. Graff Zivin, and Jialan Wang. 2010. “Superstar Extinc-

  tion.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 125 (2): 549– 89.

  Beron, Kurt J., James C. Murdoch, and Wim P. M. Vijverberg. 2003. “Why Co-

  operate? Public Goods, Economic Power, and the Montreal Protocol.” Review of

  Economics and Statistics 85 (2): 286– 97.

  Brander, James A., and Barbara J. Spencer. 1981. “Tariff s and the Extraction of

  Foreign Monopoly Rents under Potential Entry.” Canadian Journal of Economics

  14 (3): 371– 89.

  Brandt, Loren, and Xiaodong Zhu. 2000. “Redistribution in a Decentralized

  Economy: Growth and Infl ation in Reform China.” Journal of Political Economy

  108 (2): 422– 39.

  Busch, Marc L. 2001. Trade Warriors: States, Firms, and Strategic- Trade Policy in

  High- Technology Competition. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  Davies, Ronald B., and Krishna Chaitanya Vadlamannati. 2013. “A Race to the

  Bottom in Labor Standards? An Empirical Investigation.” Journal of Development

  Economics 103:1– 14.

  Dobson, Wendy, Julia Tory, and Daniel Trefl er. 2017. “Modernizing NAFTA: A

  Canadian Perspective.” In A Positive NAFTA Renegotiation, edited by Fred Berg-

  sten, 36– 49. Washington, DC: Petersen Institute for International Economics.

  Duranton, Gilles. 2011. “California Dreamin’: The Feeble Case for Cluster Policies.”

  Review of Economic Analysis 3 (1): 3– 45.

  Duranton, Gilles, and Diego Puga. 2001. “Nursery Cities: Urban Diversity, Process

  Innovation, and the Life Cycle of Products.” American Economic Review 91 (5):

  1454– 77.

  Eaton, Jonathan, and Gene M. Grossman. 1986. “Optimal Trade and Industrial

  Policy under Oligopoly.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 101 (2): 383– 406.

  Ethier, Wilfred J. 1982. “National and International Returns to Scale in the Modern

  Theory of International Trade.” American Economic Review 72 (3): 389– 405.

  Fajgelbaum, Pablo, Gene M. Grossman, and Elhanan Helpman. 2011. “Income Dis-

  tribution, Product Quality, and International Trade.” Journal of Political Economy

  119 (4): 721– 65.

  Fredriksson, Per G., and Daniel L. Millimet. 2002. “Strategic Interaction and the

  Determination of Environmental Policy across U.S. States.” Journal of Urban

  Economics 51 (1): 101– 22.

  Fujii, Hidemichi, and Shunsuke Managi. 2017. “Trends and Priority Shifts in Arti-

  fi cial Intelligence Technology Invention: A Global Patent Analysis.” RIETI Dis-

  cussion Paper Series no. 17-E066, Research Institute of Economy, Trade, and

  Industry, May.

  Goldfarb, Avi, and Catherine Tucker. 2011. “Privacy Regulation and Online Adver-

  tising.” Management Science 57 (1): 57– 71.

  ———. 2012. “Privacy and Innovation.” In Innovation Policy and the Economy,

  vol. 12, edited by Josh Lerner and Scott Stern, 65– 89. Chicago: University of

  Chicago Press.

  Artifi cial Intelligence and International Trade 491

  Grossman, Gene M., and Elhanan Helpman. 1989. “Product Development and

  International Trade.�
� Journal of Political Economy 97 (6): 1261– 83.

  ———. 1990. “Trade, Innovation, and Growth.” American Economic Review Papers

  and Proceedings 80 (2): 86– 91.

  ———. 1991. Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy. Cambridge, MA: MIT

  Press.

  Grossman, Gene M., and Alan B. Krueger. 1995. “Economic Growth and the En-

  vironment.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 110 (2): 353– 77.

  Grossman, Gene M., and Esteban Rossi- Hansberg. 2010. “External Economies and

  International Trade Redux.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 125 (2): 829– 58.

  ———. 2012. “Task Trade between Similar Countries.” Econometrica 80 (2):

  593– 629.

  Helpman, Elhanan. 1984. “Increasing Returns, Imperfect Markets, and Trade

  Theory.” In Handbook of International Economics, edited by Peter B. Kenen and

  Ronald W. Jones, 325– 65. Amsterdam: North- Holland.

  Irwin, Douglas A., and Peter J. Klenow. 1994. “Learning- by- Doing Spillovers in the

  Semiconductor Industry.” Journal of Political Economy 102 (6): 1200– 27.

  Klette, Tor Jakob, and Samuel Kortum. 2004. “Innovating Firms and Aggregate

  Innovation.” Journal of Political Economy 112 (5): 986– 1018.

  Krugman, Paul R. 1980. “Scale Economies, Product Diff erentiation, and the Pattern

  of Trade.” American Economic Review 70 (5): 950– 59.

  ———. 1986. Strategic Trade Policy and the New International Economics. Cam-

  bridge, MA: MIT Press.

  Krugman, Paul R., and Anthony J. Venables. 1995. “Globalization and the Inequal-

  ity of Nations.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 110 (4): 857– 80.

  Lim, Kevin, Daniel Trefl er, and Miaojie Yu. 2017. “Trade and Innovation: The Role

  of Scale and Competition Eff ects.” Working paper, University of Toronto.

  Manasse, Paolo, and Alessandro Turrini. 2001. “Trade, Wages, and Superstars.”

  Journal of International Economics 54 (1): 97– 117.

  Markusen, James R. 1981. “Trade and the Gains from Trade with Imperfect Com-

  petition.” Journal of International Economics 11 (4): 531– 51.

  Marx, M., and L. Fleming. 2012. “Non- compete Agreements: Barriers to Entry . . .

  and Exit?” In Innovation Policy and the Economy, vol. 12, edited by J. Lerner and S. Stern. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

  Mayer, Wolfgang. 1974. “Short- Run and Long- Run Equilibrium for a Small Open

  Economy.” Journal of Political Economy 82 (5): 955– 67.

  McLaren, John. 2000. “ ‘Globalization’ and Vertical Structure.” American Economic

  Review 90 (5): 1239– 54.

  Melitz, Marc J. 2003. “The Impact of Trade on Intra- Industry Reallocations and

  Aggregate Industry Productivity.” Econometrica 71 (6): 1695– 725.

  Miller, A. R., and C. Tucker. 2011. “Can Healthcare IT Save Babies?” Journal of

  Political Economy 119 (2): 289– 332.

  Mussa, Michael L. 1974. “Tariff s and the Distribution of Income: The Importance

  of Factor Specifi city, Substitutability, and Intensity in the Short and Long Run.”

  Journal of Political Economy 82 (6): 1191– 203.

  Oberfi eld, Ezra. 2018. “A Theory of Input- Output Architecture.” Econometrica

  86:559–89.

  Porter, Michael E. 1990. “The Competitive Advantage of Nations.” Harvard Business

  Review 68 (2): 73– 93.

  PWC. 2017. “Global Top 100 Companies by Market Capitalisation.” March 31,

  2017, update. https:// www .pwc .com/ top100. Accessed August 17, 2017 .

  492 Avi Goldfarb and Daniel Trefl er

  Rauch, James E. 1999. “Networks versus Markets in International Trade.” Journal

  of International Economics 48 (1): 7– 35.

  Rivera- Batiz, Luis A., and Paul M. Romer. 1991. “Economic Integration and Endog-

  enous Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 106 (2): 531– 55.

  Romer, Paul M. 1990. “Endogenous Technological Change.” Journal of Political

  Economy 98 (5): S71– 102.

  Rosen, Sherwin. 1981. “The Economics of Superstars.” American Economic Review

  71 (5): 845– 58.

  Ruffi

  n, Roy J., and Ronald W. Jones. 1977. “Protection and Real Wages: The Neoclas-

  sical Ambiguity.” Journal of Economic Theory 14 (2): 337– 48.

  Saxenian, AnnaLee. 1994. Regional Advantage Culture and Competition in Silicon

  Valley and Route 128. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

  Simcoe, Timothy. 2012. “Standard Setting Committees: Consensus Governance for

  Shared Technology Platforms.” American Economic Review 102 (1): 305– 36.

  Sutton, John, and Daniel Trefl er. 2016. “Capabilities, Wealth and Trade.” Journal of Political Economy 124 (3): 826– 78.

  Uyarra, Elvira, and Ronnie Ramlogan. 2012. “The Eff ects of Cluster Policy on

  Innovation Compendium of Evidence on the Eff ectiveness of Innovation Policy

  Intervention.” Technical Report, Manchester Institute of Innovation Research

  Manchester Business School, March.

  20

  Punishing Robots

  Issues in the Economics of

  Tort Liability and Innovation

  in Artifi cial Intelligence

  Alberto Galasso and Hong Luo

  20.1 Introduction

  A tort is an action that causes harm or loss, resulting in legal liability

  for the person who commits the act. The role of the tort system is to deter

  people from injuring others and to compensate those who are injured. Two

  important classes of tort law are product liability law that protects cus-

  tomers from defective or dangerous products, and medical malpractice law

  that governs professional negligence by physicians. Tort suits often make

  the headlines because of their large damages awards. For example, General

  Motors recently paid about $2.5 billion in penalties and settlements in a case

  involving faulty ignition switches linked to 124 deaths.1

  Rapid advancements in the fi eld of artifi cial intelligence and robotics have

  led to lively debates over the application of tort law to these technologies. For

  example, the diff usion of autonomous vehicles is expected to shift the focus

  of motor vehicle accident litigation from driver liability to product (i.e.,

  manufacturer) liability. Similar shifts are expected in health care because of

  advances in robot- assisted surgery and robot assistance for the elderly and

  disabled. These changes in the technological and economic landscape are

  also seen as an opportunity to redesign regulatory and liability rules. For

  Alberto Galasso is associate professor of strategic management at the University of Toronto and a research associate of the National Bureau of Economic Research. Hong Luo is the James Dinan and Elizabeth Miller Associate Professor of Business Administration at Harvard Business School.

  For acknowledgments, sources of research support, and disclosure of the authors’ material fi nancial relationships, if any, please see http:// www .nber .org/ chapters/ c14035.ack.

  1. https:// ca.reuters .com/ article/ businessNews/ idCAKBN19E25A- OCABS and Del Rossi and Viscusi (2010) document one hundred cases with punitive damages awards of at least $100

  million as of the end of 2008.

  493

  494 Alberto Galasso and Hong Luo

  example, in February 2017 the European Parliament adopted—by a large

  majority—a resolution containing recommendations for EU- wide legisla-

  tion to regulate “sophisticated robots, bots, andr
oids and other manifesta-

  tions of artifi cial intelligence” and to establish legislative instruments related

  to the liability for their actions (European Parliament 2017). An eff ective

  design and implementation of these policy changes require an understand-

  ing of how liability risk aff ects fi rms’ strategies and shapes future techno-

  logical progress.

  In an infl uential book, Porter (1990) concludes that “product liability is

  so extreme and uncertain as to retard innovation,” and he recommends a

  systematic overhaul of the US product liability system. A number of legal

  scholars share this view and warn about a potential “chilling eff ect” on

  innovation; that is, high damages awards may reduce fi rms’ willingness to

  develop new and riskier technologies, even if they are potentially superior to

  customary products (e.g., Huber 1989; Parchomovsky and Stein 2008). This

  idea that excessive liability may retard innovation also shaped high- profi le

  legal cases such as the 2008 Riegel v. Medtronic Supreme Court decision and

  is a key argument for tort reforms currently discussed in the US Congress.

  Despite the fundamental relevance of this issue, empirical work on the

  relationship between liability and innovation is scarce. Huber and Litan

  (1991) brought together a broad set of experts on fi ve sectors of the economy

  where the liability system would have had the largest impacts. Based mostly

  on surveys and historical case studies, the authors were far from reaching a

  consensus. What were commonly agreed upon, however, were the dearth of

  data and systematic evidence, and a call for future research.

  This chapter reviews the handful of empirical studies on the links between

  liability and innovation using a large sample of data. It aims to provide some

  insights into the potential impacts that liability laws and likely changes in

  the system may have on the rate and direction of innovation in robots and

  artifi cial intelligence, and to identify areas and questions for future research.2

  20.2 Liability and Innovation: An Illustrative Theoretical Model

  This section presents a simple, stylized model that explores the eff ects of

  liability risk on innovation incentives. Technologies are characterized by

  multidimensional heterogeneity. Specifi cally, a technology, i, is characterized by two parameters: b ∈ [0,1] and r ∈ [0,1]; b is the expected profi t from i

 

‹ Prev