The Apprentice Economist

Home > Other > The Apprentice Economist > Page 27
The Apprentice Economist Page 27

by Filip Palda


  Control allows you to draw a clear line between a causal and a dependent variable. Statistics then lets you say with what likelihood the link you are seeing is the result of chance. Control is part of every scientist’s way of reasoning. Yet economists have done perhaps more than any other group of thinkers to broaden the applicability of control to respond to three types of data. The worst data, from the economist’s standpoint, are those that the economy generates without any reference to the economist’s research needs. Economists responded to this unhelpful state of affairs by inventing econometrics, the science of the study of causal relations between economic variables. To make up for the uncontrolled nature of the data they invented elaborate statistical techniques. These techniques were pattern-searching algorithms that relied on the economist to provide a model. The model narrowed the range of the pattern search.

  By the 1980s the grossly subjective nature of these exercises became obvious to most economists and a cry went up for a “credibility revolution” in economic data analysis. The answer was to focus far less on developing fancy statistical techniques for reading patterns in economic tea leaves, and to instead focus on creating a second type of dataset that could be analyzed by the simple comparison of average performances between treatment and control groups.

  Controlled experiments are costly, so economists also focused on finding a third type of dataset which arose from what they called “natural experiments”. Government interventions that resembled lotteries were the best type of natural experiment to analyze. A government lottery to participate in some initiative creates similar groups of participants and non-participants. Similarity allows you to subtract the results of the treatment from the control group. What you are left with is the net effect of the program. Which is all the news that’s fit to print.

  References

  Angrist, Joshua D., and Jörn-Steffen Pischke. 2010. “The Credibility Revolution in Empirical Economics: How Better Research Design Is Taking the Con out of Econometrics.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, volume 24: 3–30.

  Galiani, Sebastian, Martín A. Rossi, and Ernesto Schargrodsky, 2011. “Conscription and Crime: Evidence from the Argentine Draft Lottery.” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, volume 3: 119–136.

  Hendry, David F. 1980. “Econometrics—Alchemy or Science?” Economica , volume 47: 387–406.

  Hicks, J.R. 1937. “Mr. Keynes and the Classics—A Suggested Interpretation.” Econometrica, volume 5: 147–159.

  Keynes, John Maynard. 1936/2007. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. (London: Macmillan).

  Lalonde, Robert J. 1986. “Evaluating the Econometric Evaluations of Training Programs with Experimental Data.” American Economic Review, volume 76: 604–620.

  Leamer, Edward E. 1983. “Let’s Take the Con Out of Econometrics.” The American Economic Review, volume 73: 31–43.

  Lucas, Robert E., Jr. 1976. “Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique.” Carnegie Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, volume 1: 19–46.

  Munk, Nina. 2013. The Idealist: Jeffrey Sachs and the Quest to End Poverty. Doubleday.

  Nunn, Nathan, and Nancy Qian. 2012. “Aiding Conflict: The Impact of U.S. Food Aid on Civil War.” NBER Working Paper No. 17794.

  Peterson, Paul, William Howell, Patrick J. Wolf, and David Campbell. 2003. “School Vouchers. Results from Randomized Experiments.” In Caroline M. Hoxby (ed.). The Economics of School Choice. University of Chicago Press: 107-144. Available at http://www.nber.org/chapters/c10087.

  Sims, C.A. 1980. “Macroeconomics and Reality.” Econometrica, volume 48: 1–48.

  Sims, Christopher A. 2010. “But Economics Is Not an Experimental Science.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, volume 24: 59–68.

  Slemrod, Joel, Marsha Blumenthal, Charles Christian. 2001. “Taxpayer Response to an Increased Probability of Audit: Evidence from a Controlled Experiment in Minnesota.” Journal of Public Economics, volume 79: 455–483.

  Slutsky, Eugen. 1937. “The Summation of Random Causes as the Source of Cyclic Processes.” Econometrica, volume 5:105-146.

  Stock, James H. 2010. “The Other Transformation in Econometric Practice: Robust Tools for Inference.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, volume 24: 83–94.

  EPILOGUE 9

  THE SEVEN STEPS TO MASTERING economics are actually not all that difficult to ascend. The difficulty lies in deciding what to do when you get to the top of the staircase.

  Economics can be a hobby or it can be a way of looking at the world. A light reading of this book will give you an idea of what the fundamental issues in economics are. The concepts of moral hazard, adverse selection, Nash equilibrium, equalizing differences, time-inconsistency, permanent income, mean-preserving spreads, efficient frontiers, Pareto efficiency, mechanism design, randomized controlled experiments, and many more will no longer be strangers to you. But while individually interesting, these islands of thought form part of larger archipelago. For what unites all of economics is a quest to establish a science of social accounting. In this pursuit the many ideas we have discussed have an important place. The method of social accounting into which they fit is known as Pareto-efficiency.

  Provided that decisions on how to use resources are taken in a context that encourages Pareto-efficiency, societies will be able to experiment with new ways of using resources without risking the wellbeing of the many. Pareto-efficiency puts a floor on the losses from social interactions involving property because any Pareto-improving exchange must benefit at least one person without harming anyone else. The result of this economic error-correction protocol is a society in which social accounts tend to be balanced. What people believe they are getting out of the “system” is at least as large as what they think they are putting into it.

  Such a belief can be the bedrock of a stable society of people who live together in large numbers but may not even know who their neighbors are. The need to understand whether the system of social accounts under which we labor is stable or will lead to ruin makes of economics a science to be taken seriously, explained with intent, and appreciated for its solemnity.

  The Apprentice Economist is no book of quips, or witty anecdotes. It is a guide to mastering some of the most important ideas that govern the individual and society. When faced with material crises governments do not call upon historians, anthropologists, political scholars, or psychologists. They call on economists. These have developed the most coherent and convincing description of how society organizes itself through a system of accounting amenable to precise analysis. Mastering this analysis is the challenge of the apprentice economist.

  Table of Contents

  PREFACE 1

  References

  SUBSTITUTION 2

  The pervasiveness of trade-offs

  The Substitution Games

  The demand curve

  The Slutsky equation

  Uses of the Slutsky Equation

  The relative philosophers

  Gold in the theory

  Substitution as the road to riches

  Renting substitution

  Prices are in your hands

  From consumers to capitalists

  Economist, economist

  Conclusion

  References

  TIME 3

  Time’s simple face

  Present value

  Permanent income, life-cycle hypothesis

  Life-cycle theory and government

  The complex face of time

  The fall and rise of growth theory

  Statistics and the social engineer

  Eine kleine time paradox

  Other applications of inter-temporal analysis

  Time in the general economic view

  A brief time of history

  Conclusion

  References

  CHANCE 4

  The constraint

  The odds ratio

  Happiness in an uncertain world

  Risk aversion

  The
troublesome question of separable utility

  Crime

  CAPM

  The risk-return frontier

  The Markowitz algorithm

  Stock market equilibrium

  Diversification, efficiency

  Rational Expectations

  Money illusion

  Self-fulfilling equilibria

  Chance and the individual

  References

  SPACE 5

  Hotelling and the competitive continuum

  Lancaster and characteristics space

  The ideology of constraints vs. preferences

  A new perspective of the meaning of price

  Rosen and the equalizing difference

  Cyanide and gold

  Equalizing differences and segregation

  Racism and the dissipation of wealth

  The curse of dimensionality

  Curving economic space

  Married in space

  The final frontier

  References

  EQUILIBRIUM 6

  Balancing social accounts

  From central control to markets

  Pareto efficiency

  Market equilibrium

  The efficiency of equilibrium

  The second welfare theorem

  The deep waters of equilibrium

  Enter Pigou

  Socialist free-marketers

  Political equilibrium

  The dark matter of economics

  References

  GAMES 7

  The essence of games

  Superior intellect of no use

  The minimax theorem

  The Nash Supremacy

  Hunting for stag

  The Schelling Point

  Subgame perfection

  The Harsanyi Renaissance

  Fusion of game theory and information economics

  Ex ludis probitas et oboedentia

  The Spence Signal

  The Vickrey auction

  Mechanism design and the size of government

  Centralized (Vickrey-Clark-Groves) vs. decentralized (Spence) mechanisms

  The mechanism zoo

  Are free markets better or worse?

  The apprenticeship of game theory

  References

  CONTROL 8

  The Dark Ages of econometrics

  The role of models

  The credible path to control

  Randomness cannot be controlled but can be measured

  Hearing through the noise

  Finding similar groups

  Randomized experiments

  A few examples

  Natural experiments

  Computer experiments

  What about prediction?

  Summary

  References

  EPILOGUE 9

 

 

 


‹ Prev