BLAIR’S BRITAIN, 1997–2007

Home > Young Adult > BLAIR’S BRITAIN, 1997–2007 > Page 29
BLAIR’S BRITAIN, 1997–2007 Page 29

by ANTHONY SELDON (edt)

that the economic crisis should be met by a rise in taxation rather than by

  cuts in public services was rapidly dismissed by Callaghan and Healey,

  and pressed, even on the left, in a somewhat lukewarm manner.12

  The undermining of Crosland’s first two presuppositions – that the

  state could control the economy, and that a beneficent state could be

  trusted to redistribute income and wealth – meant that during the long

  period of Conservative rule, from 1979 to 1997, the prospects for social

  democracy receded into the distance. Many of the things that Crosland

  insisted could not happen – a return to high unemployment, regressive

  use of the taxation system, drastic cuts in the public services and the marginalisation of the trade union movement – did in fact happen, and

  proved no barrier to Conservative electoral success. By the 1990s, if not

  earlier, it had become clear that social democrats faced a completely

  changed landscape, one dominated by new techniques of economic management, accompanied by considerable scepticism as to the value of government intervention and even of expenditure on the public services.

  After its unexpected defeat in the 1992 general election, the Labour Party

  drew the lesson, whether rightly or wrongly, that electors, whatever they

  told the opinion pollsters, would not, in the privacy of the voting booth,

  support a party which proposed higher taxes to finance the public services. Improvements in the public services, therefore, would have to be

  found in other ways.

  But there was a third presupposition that lay at the heart of Crosland’s

  analysis. It was that social democracy could be achieved in one country.

  There is indeed a paradox at the heart of social democracy. For social

  democracy, like its ancestor, socialism, is, in essence, an internationalist

  doctrine. Yet, in practice, the most favourable conditions for social

  democracy lie in highly cohesive nation-states such as Norway or Sweden.

  For it depends upon a sense of social solidarity, more likely to be present

  in small and cohesive nations than in large multicultural societies or in

  any international community. That is because social democracy requires

  citizens to feel a sense of social obligation towards their fellows such that

  they are prepared to pay in taxation to secure benefits for them. The

  stronger the sense of community, the more likely it is that such a sense of

  social obligation will be felt.

  12 See ibid. for a most valuable account of the effects of the 1976 crisis on the ethos of social

  democracy.

  

   

  William Beveridge, though far from being a social democrat, had

  appealed to such sentiments in his famous report of 1942. He had

  declared that the welfare state would give: ‘concrete expression – to the

  unity and solidarity of the nation which in war have been its bulwark

  against aggression and in peace will be its guarantees of success in the

  fight against individual want and mischance’.13

  Of course, even in a single state, the sense of solidarity is not always

  easy to achieve, and there are many who feel resentful at contributing in

  taxation to provide for the welfare of ‘spongers’. During the 1920s,

  Labour MPs told Ramsay MacDonald that their own supporters, men

  and women in low-paid jobs, were the most stringent in demanding that

  ‘scroungers’ be denied benefits.14 In late 1975, arguing that public expenditure cuts would not necessarily be unpopular, Denis Healey, Labour’s

  Chancellor, told the cabinet, ‘At the Labour clubs you’ll find there’s an

  awful lot of support for this policy of cutting public expenditure. They

  will all tell you about Paddy Murphy up the street who’s got eighteen children, has not worked for years, lives on unemployment benefit, has a

  colour television and goes to Majorca for his holidays.’15 The reference to

  ‘Paddy Murphy’ implies, what may well have been true, that for some

  Labour voters Irish immigrants were not seen as part of the national

  community. More recently, it has been argued that many voters do not

  regard non-white immigrants or asylum-seekers as part of that community, and resent being asked to contribute towards their welfare. Social

  democracy, therefore, would be more difficult to achieve in one country

  when that country was multicultural than when it was ethnically homogeneous, as seemed to be the case when Crosland wrote The Future of

  Socialism. But it would be even more difficult to achieve at the end of the

  century, by which time Britain had become subject to forces which lay

  completely outside the country – the market forces of globalisation and

  the rules of the European Union.

  Crosland had believed that social democrats could pursue policies of

  their choice largely untrammelled by foreign opinion. In the 1950s, this

  seemed to make good sense. Britain remained a sheltered economy, protected by tariffs and exchange controls. Admittedly, the Conservatives

  were gradually liberalising the economy, and in 1958 they made the pound

  13 Social Insurance and Allied Services, Cmd 6404 (London: HMSO, 1942), para. 8.

  14 See Alan Deacon, In Search of the Scrounger: The Administration of Unemployment

  Insurance in Britain, 1920–1931 (London: Bell, 1976).

  15 Tony Benn, Against the Tide: Diaries 1973–76 (London: Hutchinson, 1989), p. 461,

  13 November 1975.

   

  

  convertible. Labour criticised the Conservatives for liberalising the

  economy too quickly, for some social democrats looked longingly backwards to the days of the Attlee government when, so it seemed, intelligent

  use of controls had helped promote economic recovery, and Britain had

  appeared to be an island beacon of social democratic hope in an otherwise

  unsympathetic world.

  By the 1990s, however, it had become clear that social democracy in

  one country was no longer a feasible option. François Mitterrand had

  tried it in France in 1981, seeking to expand the economy without regard

  for the international markets, but its failure had pushed him back to

  the policy of the franc fort and tighter European integration. Gerhard

  Schroeder, when he came to power in Germany in 1998, was determined

  not to make the same mistake, and accepted, rapidly and with some gratitude, the resignation of his neo-Keynesian Finance Minister, Oskar

  Lafontaine. He too came to see in European integration a substitute for

  the ideal of social democracy in one country.

  The progress of national economies was becoming inextricably bound

  up with the international economy and the pressures of the global market.

  Governments could no longer adopt national macro-economic policies

  aimed at boosting demand, without risking punishment by the markets in

  the form of higher interest rates and falling currencies. Tony Blair showed

  that he understood this when, in his Mais lecture in 1995, he said:

  We must recognize that the UK is situated in the middle of a global market

  for capital a market which is less subject to regulation today than for

  several decades.

  An expansionary fiscal or monetary policy that is at odds with other

  economies in Europe will not be sustained
for very long. To that extent

  the room for manoeuvre of any government in Britain is already heavily

  circumscribed.16

  In addition to the constraints of the global economy, Britain, as a

  member of the European Union, was subject to its trading rules and

  to the provisions of the internal market. The European Economic

  Community, forerunner of the European Union, had not yet come into

  existence in 1956 when Crosland wrote The Future of Socialism; and Hugh

  Gaitskell, Labour’s then leader, was, together with some of his leading

  colleagues, such as Douglas Jay and Patrick Gordon Walker, positively

  hostile to it, partly on the grounds that membership would inhibit the

  16 Cited in Edmund Dell, A Strange Eventful History: Democratic Socialism in Britain

  (London: HarperCollins, 2000), p. 568.

  

   

  policies of economic planning to which a social democratic government

  ought to be committed. By the time that Tony Blair became Labour

  leader, however, Labour had become more pro-European than the

  Conservatives. Indeed, Blair made it clear that he wanted Britain to join

  the euro, an aim which he failed to achieve. Even outside the euro,

  however, Britain was becoming subject to rules which would make it

  more difficult to implement social democrat policies. The Lisbon

  Strategy, for example, agreed to by the then fifteen member states of the

  European Union in 2000, sought to achieve greater liberalisation of

  European economies and a reduction in state regulation. That meant

  further restrictions on the policy instruments available to a social democratic government. Indeed, it was fear of the extent to which the

  European Union was adhering to a neo-liberal agenda that persuaded

  many on the French left to oppose the European constitution and led to

  its defeat in the 2005 referendum.

  These developments made it difficult to see how the social democratic

  value of equality could possibly be attained. For numerous studies had

  shown that globalisation had the consequence of increasing inequalities

  even within a single state, let alone between states. Globalisation allowed

  a few to acquire massive financial rewards, while making life more

  difficult for those without marketable skills. Many on the right, indeed,

  argued that globalisation provided a new rationale for inequality. For if

  the economy was to be successful, risk-taking and enterprise must be

  given their just reward. Inequalities, therefore, could now be justified as

  an inevitable consequence of the rise of global markets, the benefits of

  which would eventually seep down to the poor. It seemed, therefore, as if

  the trends of history were leading away from social democracy, not

  towards it.

  Moreover, while globalisation had increased inequality, it had, at the

  same time, removed from national states those policy instruments which

  they would need to use to redress those inequalities. These instruments

  would now be forbidden by the rules of the European Union, the World

  Trade Organisation or similar international bodies. In The Future of

  Socialism, Crosland had deliberately confined himself to social democracy in a single state, ignoring problems of international trade and

  finance. That had seemed a perfectly plausible assumption in the 1950s; it

  had become totally implausible in the very different world of the 1990s.

  The dilemma which these changes involve for social democracy have

  been well summarised by Dominique Strauss-Kahn, a leading figure

  on the French left, and a former minister in the Mitterrand and Jospin

   

  

  governments. The success of post-war social democracy’, Strauss-Kahn

  has claimed,

  rests on the equilibrium between production and redistribution, regulated

  by the state. With globalisation, this equilibrium is broken. Capital has

  become mobile: production has moved beyond national borders, and thus

  outside the remit of state redistribution – Growth would oppose redistribution; the virtuous circle would become a vicious circle.

  The providential state has therefore been shaken. In these conditions,

  the risk is strong that it will no longer be able to control the growth of

  inequalities. Even worse, its disengagement at the precise moment when

  the mutations of capitalism are causing the growth of inequality, could

  lead the machinery of inequality to spin out of control.

  Nevertheless, for Strauss-Kahn, the stance of the left must remain the

  same. For ‘The Left is the agent of the permanent struggle against

  inequalities. To guarantee a just society, it must renew its ideology and its

  instruments in order to adapt them to contemporary realities. It must

  found a modern form of social democracy.’17 Did Tony Blair succeed in

  founding this modern form of social democracy?

  III

  A key social democratic response to the trends of globalisation has been

  to argue that its central aims can somehow be achieved by a coordinated

  social democracy operating at the transnational level. In 2001, Tony Blair

  told the Labour Party conference:

  If we follow the principles that served us so well at home – that power,

  wealth and opportunity must be in the hands of the many not the few – if

  we make that our guiding light for the global economy, then it [social

  democracy] will be a force for good and an international movement we

  should take pride in leading.

  It is becoming natural for social democrats to argue that, although

  social democracy may not be attainable at national level, it can be

  achieved at European level through the European Union. The policy

  instruments which are no longer available for redistribution at national

  level might become available at European level. The implication clearly

  is that the European Union could become an embryonic European

  17 Dominique Strauss-Kahn: `What is a Just Society? For a Radical Reformism’, in Where

  Now for European Social Democracy? (London: Policy Network, 2004), pp. 14, 16.

  

   

  government, a government which might implement social democratic

  policies at European level. That might perhaps have been possible in the

  Europe of the six from 1958 to 1973, a Europe whose governments were

  mostly Social Democrat or Christian Democrat, with a shared belief in

  the virtues of state regulation and social welfare. It is, however, utterly

  implausible in a Europe of twenty-seven member states which are at very

  different levels of economic development, and contain a wide diversity of

  ruling parties.

  The fundamental problem is that the solidarity which is, as we have

  seen, a necessary precondition for the success of social democratic policies of welfare and redistribution, is hardly present at European level.

  Many supporters of European union, including European social democrats, hope that European institutions might create a synergy so as to

  create a new sense of solidarity and new habits of working together, at

  European level, so that a European government could somehow replicate
r />   the governments of the member states. For that to happen, however, individual states would have to accept that they could be outvoted by other

  states and have policies imposed upon them which they did not support.

  The parliamentarians of, say, France, with a government of the right,

  would have to accept that social democrats were in a majority in the

  Europe of twenty-seven member states, and could impose social democratic policies upon the French, which their national government and

  their national voters have rejected. Such a condition only has to be stated

  for its utopian nature to be recognised. Indeed, even within member

  states, it is not easy to secure the support of members of subordinate

  nationalities for policies decided by national parliaments. One important

  motivation behind Scottish devolution was that the Scots resented being

  in a permanent minority during the long period of Conservative government at Westminster between 1979 and 1997. The Scots were beginning

  to see themselves not as a minority in the United Kingdom but as a

  majority in Scotland. They would perhaps be even more upset were they

  to be regarded as a permanent minority in Europe. It would, however, be

  a consequence of social democracy at European level that Britain, like the

  other member states, could have policies imposed upon her that her government and electors had rejected. Such an outcome is hardly likely to

  prove acceptable. Social democracy at European level, therefore, is likely

  to remain a pipe-dream.

  If the aims of social democracy have been made vastly more difficult

  of attainment because of the transfer of power upwards from national

  institutions, these difficulties have been compounded by the transfer of

   

  

  powers downwards to devolved bodies by the Blair government. As a

  result of devolution, the non-English parts of the United Kingdom –

  Scotland, Wales and Northern Ireland – now enjoy devolved government

  and a high degree of autonomy in their domestic affairs. Devolution was

  also offered to the English regions, but rejected by a four-to-one majority

  in the first region to be offered it, the North-East, thought to be most

  sympathetic to it, in 2004.

  Devolution was a policy which Blair had inherited from John Smith,

  and there are those who believe that he had little enthusiasm for it. Indeed,

 

‹ Prev