Book Read Free

BLAIR’S BRITAIN, 1997–2007

Page 35

by ANTHONY SELDON (edt)


  claw-back rate lower down. The balance of informed observer opinion is

  generally with him in this. Whether MW raises or reduces total employment depends critically on where it is set. A modest MW will tend to raise

  rates of pay – and, critically, the number of jobs available – for very low-paid

  workers in narrow labour markets where employers do not discriminate in

  the wages they pay for such workers, and find – or at least believe – that they

  have to raise the common rate of pay to attract extra staff. This is known as

  ‘labour monopsony’. In markets where labour varies widely according to

  perceived productivity, and firms can hire any amount of labour of a particular quality at a given price, imposing a MW anywhere will either be

  irrelevant (for those whose productivity exceeds the MW) or unambiguously job-destroying (for those below it). Evidence on the issue is contested, but most good studies34 tend to find that MW increases are good for

  raising the earnings of the low paid without endangering employment.

  Brown’s labour market reforms appear to have had Blair’s blessing.

  And if they squabbled on many matters, particularly Europe, and gave

  their civil servants what became known as ‘teebeegeebees’ at times when

  the two men were due to meet, there were other issues, too, on which they

  clearly saw eye to eye. One was Africa; another, climate change. Both

  became increasingly important in the later years. In 2005, Brown drove

  through an historic set of international agreements on debt relief for the

  world’s poorest countries, most of them in Africa, with keen support

  both from Blair and from the exceptionally talented Secretary of State,

  Hilary Benn. Blair’s intervention here was important, since he will have

  helped to neutralise official opposition from Washington on this issue.

  And 2006 saw the publication of Sir Nicholas Stern’s Review on the

  Economics of Climate Change, which was prepared inside the Treasury,

  with Brown’s blessing, but as a submission in the first instance to Blair.

  Climate change is also a matter of distribution, of justice, but this time of

  34 D. Card and A. Krueger, Myth and Measurement: The New Economics of the Minimum

  Wage (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1997) is probably the most influential

  US study of this.

  

   

  distribution across generations, not within them. Much of Blair’s final

  year in office was devoted to informing (and raising the profile of) the

  debate that threats that global warming posed for the world, and trying

  hard to counter the reluctance of several governments, most notably the

  American and the Chinese, to consider what most experts now consider

  appropriate, indeed urgently necessary, policy responses to them. Perhaps the two men sometimes competed for the limelight on these two

  issues, almost as much as they cooperated. Perhaps the view they took on

  both issues reflected an emotional, moral commitment to do good today

  that took precedence over some of the analytical longer-run complexities.35 Perhaps, in the evening twilight of his premiership, Blair was

  becoming desperate to salvage a reputation so grievously tarnished by

  Iraq. Yet it may be that, in time, these achievements of the Blair–Brown

  partnership come to be regarded as no less important than the Blair years’

  record of macro-economic stability.

  Conclusions

  How new was New Labour economic policy under Blair? And how

  Labour? Labour participated in Churchill’s coalition from 1940 to 1945,

  and had formed two short-lived minority governments between the wars.

  But it was in and after 1945 that Labour came into its own. It was in power

  for three spells of five to six years, usually (but not always) with a working

  majority: 1945–51, 1964–70 and 1974–9.

  Labour devalued sterling in 1949 and 1967, and saw it depreciate

  sharply in 1974–6. Labour extended public ownership marginally in

  1964–70 and 1974–9, and massively in 1945–51. Labour increased

  income tax rates in all three periods, reducing the post-tax income of top

  earners most. It was here that the contrast with Blair’s administrations

  was starkest. Sterling appreciated by some 14 % in his decade. Labour

  nationalised nothing in these years, and actually continued privatisations

  that had begun under Thatcher. The main structure and rates of income

  tax were changed very little under Blair. In his decade,36 the few changes

  that were enacted were mostly downwards.

  35 Writing off a deeply indebted debtor’s debt may, for all its merits, have the unfortunate sideeffect of discouraging future lending. And responding to climate change by a big jump in

  taxes on oil may do nothing to alleviate the problem, or curb emissions, if all it does, as

  argued in Sinclair, ‘The Optimum Rate of Inflation’, is to squeeze the price the oil seller gets.

  36 This observation is only slightly qualified by the facts that a 1% contribution, seemingly

  indefinitely postponable, to National Insurance has been levied since 2003 on top earnings, and the point at which the 40% rate first applies has slid, relative to incomes.

      

  

  In some other respects, there is more continuity with previous Labour

  governments. The principle that Labour governments could not, and

  must not try to, spend their way to full employment was first expounded

  forcefully by Callaghan in 1976. It was Callaghan’s premiership that saw

  the introduction of cash limits on departmental spending, and also of

  monetary targets, the rather clumsy and indirect forerunner of inflationtargeting. Brown’s decision to say ‘No, not yet at least’ to the euro in 2003

  mirrors the Callaghan government’s decision to keep Britain out of the

  European Communities’ fledging Exchange Rate Mechanism in March

  1979. And Blair’s successful campaign to delete Clause 4 from Labour’s

  traditional constitution (the commitment to extend public ownership)

  counterpointed his predecessor Gaitskell’s spirited but failed attempt to

  achieve this back in 1962.

  Where previous post-war Labour governments had failed, Blair and

  Brown reasoned, was in the way they had allowed supporters’ expectations

  about what could be achieved early on to run out of control – and then

  drive the government into a shaming retreat in the face of hostile financial

  markets. Under Blair, therefore, Labour courted big business and big

  finance sedulously in opposition and in power. The trades unions,

  Labour’s traditional paymasters, were sidelined and ignored. None of the

  Conservative government’s main anti-union legislation was repealed. Any

  resulting shortage in Labour’s election war funds was to be filled by gifts,

  or later loans, with no binding commitment to repay, from very rich businessmen. And after the election victory in 1997, supporters’ early hopes

  were restrained (and financiers’ nerves soothed) by the simple device of

  adhering rigidly to the previous government’s rather restrictive spending

  limits.37 In the dark arts of public relations, it is a sacred principle to ‘Get

  the bad news out first’. Blair and Brown obeyed this
tenet to the letter.

  When the lid came off, in 1999, it was not long before health spending

  came to be raised sharply. But a hasty John Reid, the then Health Secretary,

  was cleverly outmanoeuvred and succumbed to the wiles of the British

  Medical Association. So much of the extra money, it turned out, was lavished on extra pay in return for reduced work. Some was frittered on extra

  staff and extra pay for hospital administrators. And some was spent on an

  ambitious computerisation project, which revealed all too clearly how the

  Prime Minister’s imagination, and distaste for slow traditional administrative procedures, could run ahead of good reason and careful decisiontaking. Furthermore the Blair–Brown partnership’s devotion to PFI

  37 Limits that, it is thought, the outgoing government might well have relaxed had they won

  the election.

  

   

  projects, in health and education, at least led, unlike Scotland’s new

  Parliament, to timely completions. But government’s inability to understand the private companies’ small print and fee structure was to bequeath a

  legacy of financial poison for the health trusts that had been induced to enter

  them. In these details, Blair’s administration was blind and incompetent.

  Yet in many, even bigger things, Brown did well. And Blair did well too,

  whatever his motives, by just letting Brown get on with it. In granting

  operational independence for the Bank, in retaining the Lawson–Thatcher tax structure and anti-union laws, and in not joining the euro,

  the Blair–Brown duumvirate showed considerable wisdom. They inherited a strong macro-economy from Major, and a policy framework set

  mainly by Thatcher. But their greatest achievement was to consolidate the

  revolution of their Conservative predecessors.

  References

  Abreu, D. and D. Pearce (2007), ‘Bargaining, Reputation and Equilibrium

  Selection in Repeated Games with Contracts’, Econometrica, v. 75, 653–710

  Aghion, P. and P. Howitt (1998), Endogenous Growth Theory, MIT Press.

  Allen, W., R. Batley, E. Baroudy, B. Paulson and P. Sinclair (2007), Growth in

  Britain, University of Birmingham, mimeo

  Atkinson, A. and J. Stiglitz (1980), Lectures in Public Economics, McGraw Hill

  Barker, K. (2004), Delivering Stability: Securing Our Future Housing Needs, Final

  Report, HMSO

  Barro, R. and D. Gordon (1983), ‘Rules, Discretion and Reputation in a Model of

  Monetary Policy’, Journal of Monetary Economics, v. 12, 101–21

  Brealey, R., C. Goodhart, J. Healey, G. Hoggarth, C. Shu, and P. Sinclair (2001),

  Financial Stability and Central Banks, Routledge

  Card, D. and A. Krueger, Myth and Measurement: The New Economics of the

  Minimum Wage, Princeton University Press

  Doppelhofer, G., R. Miller and X. Sala-i-Martin (2004), ‘Determinants of LongTerm Growth: a Bayesian Averaging of Classical Estimates (Bace) Approach’,

  American Economic Review, v. 94. 813–35

  Driver, R. and P. Westaway (2005), Concepts of Equilibrium Exchange Rates, in

  Exchange Rates, Capital Flows and Policy, eds. R. Driver, P. Sinclair and C.

  Thoenissen, Routledge.

  Emerson, M., D. Gros and A. Italiener (1992), One Market, One Money, Oxford

  University Press

  Hall, R. and C. Jones (2007), ‘The Value of Life and the Rise in Health Spending’,

  Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122, 39–72

  H.M.Treasury (2003a), ‘UK Membership of the Single Currency: an Assessment of

  the Five Economic Tests’, cm 5776, 9 June

      

  

  H.M.Treasury (2003b), ‘UK Membership of the Single Currency: EMU

  Studies’, (http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/documents/international_issues/

  the_euro/assessment/studies)

  Kaldor, N. (1956, An Expenditure Tax, Allen and Unwin

  Lagos, R. and R. Wright (2005), ‘A Unified Framework for Monetary Theory and

  Policy Analysis’, Journal of Political Economy, v.113, 463–84

  Lucas, R. E. (1988), ‘On the Mechanics of Development’, Journal of Monetary

  Economics, v. 22, 3–42

  Lucas, R.E. (1990), ‘Supply Side Economics: an Analytical Review’, Oxford

  Economic Papers, v. 42, 293–316

  McCallum, J. (1995), ‘National Borders Matter: Canada – US Regional Trade

  Patterns’, American Economic Review, v. 85. 615–23

  Miles, D. (2004), ‘The UK Mortgage Market: Taking a Longer-Term View’, Final

  Report and Recommendations, HMSO

  Mirrlees, J. A. (1971), ‘An Exploration in the Theory of Optimum Income

  Taxation’, Review of Economic Studies, v. 38, 175–208

  National Audit Office (2001), the Auction of Radio Spectrum for the Third

  Generation of Mobile Telephones, Report by the Comptroller and Auditor

  General, House of Commons 233, 19 October

  Pesaran, H., V. Smith and R. Smith (2007), ‘What if the UK or Sweden had Joined

  the Euro in 1999? An Empirical Evaluation Using a Global VAR’,

  International Journal of Finance and Economics, v. 12, 55–87.

  Powell, A. (2003), ‘The Argentine Crisis: Bad Luck, Bad Management, Bad Policies,

  Bad Advice’, Brookings Trade Forum, Brookings Institution Press.

  Rocheteau, G. and R. Wright (2005), ‘Money in Competitive Equilibrium, in

  Search Equilibrium, and in Competitive Search Equilibrium’, Econometrica,

  v. 73, 175–202

  Rogoff, K. (1985), ‘The Optimal Degree of Commitment to an Intermediate

  Monetary Target’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, v. 100, 1169–89.

  Romer, P. (1990), ‘Endogenous Technological Change’, Journal of Political

  Economy, v.98, S71–102

  Rose, A. (2000), ‘One Money, One Market: Estimating the Effect of Common

  Currencies on Trade’, Economic Policy, v. 30, 7–45

  Sinclair, P. (1994), ‘On the Optimum Trend of Fossil Fuel Taxation’, Oxford

  Economic Papers, v. 46, 869–77

  Sinclair, P. (2003), ‘The Optimum Rate of Inflation: an Academic Perspective’,

  Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, v 43, 343–51

  Stern, N.H. et al (2006), The Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change,

  http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/reviews/stern_review_economics_climate_

  change.

  Turner, A. (2005), A New Pension Settlement for the Twenty-first Century, HMSO10

  11

  New Labour, new capitalism

   

  ‘Labour as a party not only believes that economic dynamism and social

  justice must go hand in hand but that creating and maintaining the right

  environment for enterprise and wealth creation is a policy priority.’

  Tony Blair launching the 2005 general election manifesto

  ‘The challenge of globalisation needs a strong and vibrant trade union

  movement standing up for its members in a coherent and intelligent way.’

  Tony Blair to the TUC annual conference in 2002

  ‘The partnership between us is essential and I intend to ensure that it

  remains positive and firm.’

  Tony Blair speaking at the Confederation of British Industry annual

  conference on 17 November 2003

  Tony Blair spoke in Manchester on 30 April 2007 as part of his legacy

  tour. His subject that day was the world of paid work and the
New

  Labour government’s contribution to its evolution during his ten years

  as Prime Minister. In a comprehensive presentation Blair set out what he

  believed had always been a coherent and credible programme, designed

  to modernise Britain’s labour markets and its employment relations in a

  strategic political response to the pressures imposed on the country’s

  economy by the dynamics of globalisation and relentless technological

  innovation.

  ‘Work, the fact of work and the changed nature of work were central to

  the government’s economic and social policy from the beginning’, he

  claimed.1 Unlike previous Labour governments, his administration had

  sought to develop a new role for the state in its engagement with the wider

  political economy as it tried to encourage economic efficiency with social

  justice in the workplace. The state’s primary purpose was no longer either

  to control or regulate, not even to protect employees from the adverse

  11 For the full text of Blair’s Manchester lecture see the Downing Street website: www.gov.uk.

  

   ,  

  

  consequences of structural change or ‘intervene to make employers more

  flexible’ in their management of labour. Instead, modern government

  was needed to assist in meeting the insatiable demands of capital, to

  ensure private companies could compete effectively in open markets and

  to provide more investment in education and training to assist in ensuring that the UK could boast a high-quality, high-productivity economy. A

  positive approach by the state that encouraged risk-taking and wealth

  creation was the way forward. The New Labour project was to embrace

  global capitalism with enthusiasm in a radical break with Labour’s troubled socialist past.

  Blair’s most important achievement was to identify his government

  with the forces of international finance capital. Under his government the

  City of London grew into one of the successful centres of globalisation.

  By 2007 nearly half the country’s two million people employed in financial services were concentrated in the booming world of banks, insurance

  houses, venture capital companies and management consultants that

 

‹ Prev