BLAIR’S BRITAIN, 1997–2007

Home > Young Adult > BLAIR’S BRITAIN, 1997–2007 > Page 39
BLAIR’S BRITAIN, 1997–2007 Page 39

by ANTHONY SELDON (edt)


  (London: TUC, 2004), and P. Davies and M. Freeland, Towards a Flexible Labour

  Market (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2007).

  and paternity leave owed much to pressure from his wife Cherie.

  Cridland admitted that the dramatic growth in worker rights was to cause

  his own organisation some difficulties. Employers found it was relatively

  easy to remain united in resistance to familiar trade union collectivist

  demands, and to press Blair with considerable success in ensuring

  employer interests were looked after through the dilution, delay or even

  abandonment of much of what trade unions wanted. Downing Street was

  always willing to listen and act over business complaints about the trade

  union agenda. But such an approach was far less possible when it came to

  resistance to the creation of individual employee rights, especially when

  Blair argued that all he was doing was trying to help promote the emergence of civilised workplaces that would help to improve productivity

  and corporate performance through a strategy of economic efficiency

  and social justice, but framed on business terms.

  For their part, many trade unions were often either hostile or ambivalent in their reaction to the individual rights agenda. Ideally they would

  have preferred measures that were limited only to trade union members.

  Now all employees would be covered by a framework of individual rights.

  The real beneficiaries of Blair’s individualistic workplace agenda

  were women, either in employment or seeking a paid job. Many of the

  minimum rights sought to improve their work/life balance in the face of

  increasing workplace stress and the feminisation of the labour force. By

  continental European standards the new rights may have looked limited

  

   

  and inadequate. But at least they seemed to recognise at last the persistence of workplace gender inequalities made worse by the growth of the

  female labour force and the inadequacy of earlier equal pay and gender

  discrimination laws, as well as the insatiable demands of companies that

  were unmet by the traditional nine-to-five working time arrangements

  and the need for part-time employees. The new emphasis on employment flexibility ensured there would be a much greater focus on women

  and their needs at work.

  Weaknesses of the hybrid model

  Blair’s determination to introduce labour market and employment relations reforms in order to help capital maximise its potential was not

  entirely consistent. Despite his well-meaning rhetoric as Prime Minister,

  he surprisingly failed to devote much of his time to resolving the

  country’s familiar intractable long-term supply-side problems, whose

  tangled roots lay deep in its economic history. The most serious lack of

  significant progress could be seen in failing to raise the quality of the

  workforce at the lower end of the labour market. A succession of authoritative international reports between 2000 and 2007 revealed the extent of

  the UK’s relatively poor skills performance during the Blair years. Among

  advanced industrialised nations the country suffered from a particularly

  chronic lack of workers equipped with recognisable and adaptable intermediate qualifications. In 2006 it was still estimated that as many as a

  third of all adults of working age lacked any recognised skills at all, or

  were at best low-skilled. This was a much higher proportion than could

  be found in competitor countries such as France and Germany, which

  were often the object of the Prime Minister’s scathing criticism for their

  supposed labour market deficiencies. The Blair record on skills and training was depressingly similar to that of his predecessors. The apparent lack

  of any urgent official concern for the plight of the country’s millions of

  poorly qualified or unqualified workers remained a puzzle, especially as

  Blair appeared to recognise that the country’s long-term prosperity lay

  through the creation of a more highly skilled, highly motivated labour

  force. A review commissioned by the government from Lord Leitch, and

  published at the end of 2006, urgently emphasised that the government

  needed to give a much greater priority to carrying through radical

  reforms if it wanted the UK to compete successfully in the global

  economy. It seemed New Labour’s creation of the Learning and Skills

  Councils, as well as the Regional Development Agencies, had made little

   ,  

  

  significant impact on the problem. The Train to Gain programme, the

  newly formed Centres for Vocational Excellence and government-funded

  employer training schemes were further attempts to deal with skill weaknesses. But by the end of his premiership this was an area where Blair

  could not point to much tangible advance. Hopes were pinned on the

  restoration of apprenticeships as well as a national training programme

  for employers to be launched in 2007, under which the government

  offered to subsidise courses for their existing employees to be up-skilled.

  But this seemed too little, too late. Leitch argued that despite the substantial promise of more investment and reform the UK could only expect to

  run to stand still by 2020 in the skills of its labour force.

  Many of Blair’s own advisers admitted the skills and training issue did

  not receive the government attention that it deserved. Lord Layard

  suggested it was Blair’s ‘greatest failure’ in his labour market strategy.10 But

  as an official report pointed out in 2004, ‘Unless the UK has a requisite

  stock of skills, including entrepreneurship, innovation, managerial

  effectiveness and technical capability then the goal of achieving a high

  value added high productivity economy will remain elusive. The extent of

  the skills gap far exceeds recruitment problems.’11 The long tail of poorly

  motivated and under-qualified workers, as well as inefficient and poorly

  managed private sector companies, continued to place a serious questionmark over the country’s longer-term ability to secure a competitive

  advantage in globalising markets. Moreover the skills failure was closely

  related to other familiar weaknesses. As the 2004 government skills audit

  pointed out, ‘Skills strategies go hand in hand with policies and strategies

  to increase levels of capital investment within companies, develop new

  products and processes and capture new markets.’

  International comparisons did not suggest private companies were

  allocating sufficient of their financial resources to research and development investment. ‘In recent years the aggregate amount of spending on

  research and development in the UK has lagged behind that of our international competitors’, complained a 2004 study from the government’s

  own Office of National Statistics. It spoke of a ‘comparative lack of entrepreneurial spirit’ among Britain’s employers compared with the United

  States, and the poor quality of much of its management.12 In 1999 the

  United States invested 25% more capital per hour worked than in this

  10 Author’s interview with Lord Richard Layard, April 2007.

  11 Department of Education and Skills, Skills Audit (London: TSO, 2004).

  12 Craig Lindsay, Labour Productivity, Labour Mark
et Trends (London: Office of National

  Statistics, November 2004), p. 47.

  

   

  country, while France invested 60% more and Germany 32% more. In

  2005 the pre-budget statement revealed that British business invested

  1.24% of gross domestic product in research and development but this

  compared with 1.37% in France, 1.73% in Germany and 1.87% in the

  United States. The Treasury was compelled to admit that Britain ‘was less

  effective at realising the commercial potential of research and business

  expenditure and its current aggregate level was below the average of

  OECD countries’. Nor was the UK impressive in its growth in innovation.

  In 2000 innovation companies in the country represented 62% of

  turnover and 54% of total employment. ‘In most other European

  economies the shares were significantly higher’, wrote Ian Brinkley at the

  Work Foundation.13

  The country was rescued from such inadequacy with the dramatic

  growth of inward migration by mainly young workers with adaptable

  skills and drive from central and eastern Europe after their countries

  entered the European Union as full members in January 2004. In addition, British employers in both the public and private sectors were compelled to travel through the developing world in search of people who

  were willing to come and work in Britain in the health service and other

  professions. Cherry-picking expeditions at the expense of the poorest in

  the world were able to cover over some of the inadequacies of the

  country’s indigenous labour force.

  But Britain’s continuing supply-side problems helped to explain why it

  still achieved relatively low levels of comparative labour productivity

  during the Blair years. In an April 2005 assessment the National Institute

  for Economic and Social Research (NIESR) concluded that there had

  been ‘no obvious improvement’ in UK productivity performance since

  1997. It is true that the country was no longer falling behind France and

  other competitor European nations in the way it had done for the forty

  years after the end of the Second World War, but the NIESR noted that it

  was ‘not obviously closing the gap with France and we have stopped

  closing the gap with the United States’.14 Official figures for 2005 showed

  little productivity improvement either. Measured by gross domestic

  product per worker, the UK figure was still 26% below that of the United

  States and 10% less than France. The picture was little better when productivity performance was measured by gross domestic product per hour

  13 Ian Brinkley, Defining the Information Economy (London: Work Foundation, July 2006).

  14 National Institute for Economic and Social Research, in National Institute Economic

  Review, no. 192, April 2005.

   ,  

  

  worked. Germany, France and the United States continued to be ahead of

  the UK in that measurement.15

  While the UK appeared to develop strongly as an information

  economy under Blair, it did not look so impressive by international comparison. In 1994 the UK invested 3.5% of its gross domestic product in

  knowledge activities, but by 2002 this had risen to 3.7%, only a modest

  0.2% improvement over the period. The Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development did not even classify the country as a highinvestment economy. That term was used to cover Sweden, the United

  States, Finland, South Korea, Denmark, Japan and Canada.

  A further profound weakness that persisted in the UK labour market

  under Blair was the existence of intractable social inequalities. The

  country’s workforce came to represent an hourglass, with a small number

  of highly skilled winners at the top and a huge proportion at the bottom.

  A devastating report, The Cost of Exclusion, published by the LSE’s Centre

  for Economic Performance for the Prince’s Trust in April 2007, estimated

  that as many as 20% of the young aged sixteen to twenty-four in 2005 –

  nearly a million – were not in education, training or employment, with a

  calculated loss to the economy of £10 million a day. It reported that this

  finding showed there had been ‘little change since the mid 1990s’ when

  Blair became Prime Minister.16 Clearly the UK had still a long way to go

  before it could claim success in the reconciliation of economic efficiency

  with social justice in a modern economy.

  Back to the future? The hybrid model in perspective

  Under Blair a new ill-defined hybrid market model began to emerge in

  the UK which was exemplified in his policies towards capital and labour.

  Whether the resulting mixed achievement – admired by right-wing

  European politicians such as French President Nicolas Sarkozy, Italy’s

  Silvio Berlusconi and Spain’s José Maria Aznar – could be copied by other

  countries as an effective response to globalisation elsewhere was highly

  debatable. Certainly evidence of any countervailing influence in the creation of an alternative political economy model was hard to find in the

  UK by 2007.

  A century earlier, in what came to be known as the progressive era in

  the years leading up to the outbreak of the First World War in August

  15 Office of National Statistics, press release, 21 February 2007.

  16 LSE Centre for Economic Performance , The Cost of Exclusion (London: LSE, April 2007).

  

   

  1914, the British Labour movement – among others – had sought to

  create a new and better world for all, but especially the manual working

  class. This had involved demanding the creation of regulated labour

  markets through the actions of an increasingly paternalistic state to

  protect the poor, old and vulnerable, and to eliminate the curses of

  poverty and unemployment. The social policy agenda was coupled with

  the emergence of trade unions which aimed to improve the material

  needs of their members through the voluntarist system of industrial relations based on autonomous trade union bargaining with employers, and

  the negotiation of non-legally binding collective agreements and joint

  consultation. Now it seemed that the New Labour project under

  Blair/Brown had made Britain safe for the triumph of global capitalism

  through rebalancing the relations between capital and labour. This was

  quite an achievement. Whether the results would turn out to prove stable,

  permanent or morally defensible was, however, quite another matter.

  Blair and Brown had moved Britain dramatically with the grain of market

  forces as they consolidated and advanced Margaret Thatcher’s inheritance. They did not seriously seek to challenge any vested corporate interests outside the trade unions. Under them Labour abandoned any

  pretence that its purpose was the creation of a more socially equitable

  society rooted in the pursuit of left-wing values such as equality, liberty

  and fraternity. In 2007 it was to be the forces of capital and not labour in

  Britain who could now proclaim with a sense of triumph, ‘We are the

  masters now.’

  But the Blair effect on labour markets and employment relations was

  to prove more transformati
onal than even this might suggest. During his

  years as Prime Minister the Labour movement virtually ceased to exist as

  a recognisable entity. Its institutions ossified and its social base collapsed,

  partly due to the continuing decline of a skilled manual working class that

  had provided so much of Labour’s organisational and moral strength in

  the workplaces and in civil society during much of the last century. Rapid

  occupational changes in society were mainly responsible for this profound transformation, which had gathered pace after the 1970s. It was

  not due to the deliberate actions of Blair or anybody else in political life.

  But perhaps he more than most of his contemporaries sensed intuitively

  what was going on and responded to it by seeking to reflect the consequences of the new realities within his political project. There was more

  than spin and hype to this phenomenon. Blair demonstrated why the UK

  was unable to transform itself into a genuinely social democratic country

  like those in northern Europe. The individualism of the country’s indus- ,  

  

  trial relations and employment system reflected what were always deep

  and stubborn social forces that went back to the nineteenth century and

  industrialisation. From Ramsay MacDonald to John Smith, the Labour

  Party claimed that an important part of its moral purpose was to transform Britain into a classless society and to replace, or at least modify, the

  workings of the market economy through the creation of an economic

  model that was based on social justice and equity rather than profit

  and competition. But even in the aftermath of the Second World War,

  when T. H. Marshall’s concept of social citizenship was widely recognised

  by the political class, most people seemed more concerned for their own

  well-being within their own private family networks and the wider civil

  society. Most regarded paid work as an instrumental means needed for

  the pursuit of a better life and were deeply sceptical, even hostile, to the

  role of an intrusive centralising state, however well-meaning it might be

  in theory. The reports of the Mass Observation surveys suggest this

  popular attitude was even prevalent in the age of Attlee in the 1940s.17

 

‹ Prev