Book Read Free

BLAIR’S BRITAIN, 1997–2007

Page 64

by ANTHONY SELDON (edt)


  In general the Blair government tended to concentrate on health services. Its policies for social services built on the earlier shift to a mixed

  economy of care. Spending rose faster than before but only at about half

  the rate of spending in the NHS. An excellent independent regulator

  reported progress in access and quality. The mixed economy led to a

  greater flexibility in developing new services. For example, increased

  access to intensive home care was almost entirely met by private

  providers, as was care for people with the most severe learning disabilities. Social services showed lessons about the gains to a real mixed

  economy which were generally unheeded for the NHS.

  17 Ibid.

  18 Tony Blair, Our Nation’s Future – Social Exclusion, 5 September 2006.

  19 Ibid.

      

  

  Developing NHS IT. The aspiration of acquiring an electronic patient

  record was a noble one. Connecting for Health could point to some

  results including the introduction of access to broadband and digital

  transmission of X-rays in the London area – but the programme as a

  whole by 2007 was a long way behind schedule. It has also changed direction, aiming to develop previous legacy systems rather than replace

  them.20 The previous achievements of GPs had been underestimated and

  the top-down approach had not worked well. The aspiration was highly

  praiseworthy but an approach which emphasised local initiative as well

  as system integration would have got results far more quickly at a far

  lower cost.

  The missing dimension – reliable international comparisons

  The changes were affected by the crucial problems faced by central planners that they may be implementing yesterday’s system. While The NHS

  Plan pointed to a huge centralised system, international experience was

  moving in a totally different direction.

  The first funding wave of The NHS Plan was based on comparisons of

  NHS spending as compared to GDP shares in the rest of Europe. The

  policy conclusion was that the UK should move with extreme speed to

  spend more than the European average. Such comparisons ignored some

  crucial ‘health warnings’ about international comparisons.

  Health systems can be divided into those with a strong primary care

  base as against those with direct access to specialist care and fee-forservice. As Table 18.1 shows, the spending levels for the first type of

  system, at 8–9% of GDP, are well below those for the second type, at

  10–12%. Yet all studies of population health, treatment outcomes and

  patient access show that the first type of system delivers results which are

  at least as good and in many dimensions better than the second.

  Recent research on the US health maintenance organisation Kaiser

  Permanente sponsored by the Department of Health has itself confirmed

  that the first type of system in a regional context can indeed deliver very

  effective results. The original research showed that on an adjusted PPP

  basis the NHS spent $1,784 per head while Kaiser Permanente spent

  $1,984 per head.21 These results were fully adjusted for differences in the

  20 Richard Granger, Director General of IT for the NHS, oral evidence to the House of

  Commons Health Committee, 26 April 2007, HC 422–i.

  21 Richard Feachem et al., ‘Getting More for their Dollar: A Comparison of the NHS with

  California’s Kaiser Permanente’, British Medical Journal, 324, 2002: 135–43.

  

   

  Table 18.1. Growth of expenditure on health 1990–2001, health

  spending as percentage of GDP

  1990

  2001

  Primary care-led systems:

  Denmark

  8.5

  8.6

  Finland

  7.8

  7.0

  Netherlands

  8.0

  8.9

  New Zealand

  6.9

  8.1

  Spain

  6.7

  7.5

  Sweden

  8.2

  8.7

  United Kingdom

  6.0

  7.6

  Fee-for-service-led systems:

  Belgium

  7.4

  9.0

  France

  8.6

  9.5

  Germany

  8.5

  10.7

  Switzerland

  8.5

  10.9

  United States

  11.9

  13.9

  Source: OECD Health Data, 2004

  age composition of patients and in the differences in the range of services

  provided by the two systems. Later comparisons sponsored by the

  Department of Health showed that: ‘For the 11 causes selected for study,

  total bed use in the NHS is three-and-a-half times that of Kaiser’s standardized rate.’22

  The level of spending generated in the first system reflects the costs of

  providing certain services involving primary care access, referral and protocol-driven secondary care. If this system is associated with higher levels

  of spending, this implies either higher costs than could be prudently

  managed or higher levels of activity. There is good international evidence

  that high levels of health spending are often associated with the flat of the

  curve – with waste and low quality in care. Detailed criticisms have been

  made, for example, of the low standard of cancer care in Germany and the

  poor quality of prescribing in France. An OECD summary concluded

  that: ‘While richer countries tend to spend more on health, there is still

  22 Chris Ham et al., ‘Hospital Bed Utilisation in the NHS, Kaiser Permanente and the US

  Medicare Programme: Analysis of Routine Data’, British Medical Journal, 29, 2003:

  1257–60.

      

  

  great variation in spending among countries with comparable incomes.

  Even more importantly the highest spending systems are not necessarily

  the ones that do best in meeting performance goals.’23

  Canada supplies a particularly strong example of how funding without

  reform may in fact lead to increases in waiting times and greater access

  problems. Between 1993 and 2003, average waiting times have risen 70%

  over a period when real spending per head rose 21%, in constant 1995

  dollars, from $1,836 to $2,223. New Zealand has had similar problems,

  with a 40% increase in real-terms spending from 2000 to 2006 but a fall in

  the number of elective procedures and a rise in waiting times. Thus higher

  levels of spending are often taken to conceal problems of low productivity.

  A more considered international comparison would certainly have

  pointed to a strong case for some additional funding. UK spending was

  in fact below the GDP shares found in tax-funded/primary care-led

  systems. There were also serious deficiencies in some key areas of care

  where a combination of new incentives with extra funding was required.

  The international evidence, however, pointed to a phased increase in

  spending to 8–9% of GDP. The increase to 10–11% of GDP was not supported by international evidence.

  The Bla
ir diagnosis of under-funding was also hard to reconcile with

  UK capability in primary care, its potential for lower-cost public health

  programmes and the targeting of health spending on most cost-effective

  programmes through NICE. It also tended to concentrate management

  attention on the spending of extra funding rather than on making better

  use of the funding that was already there. The various NHS plans have

  ignored the real lessons of international experience which were recently

  summarised by the OECD:

  Ultimately increasing efficiency may be the only way of reconciling rising

  demands for health care with public financing constraints. Cross-country

  data suggest that there is scope for improvement in the cost-effectiveness of

  health care systems. This is because the health sector is typically characterized by market failures and heavy public intervention, both of which can

  generate excess or misallocated spending. The result is wasted resources

  and missed opportunities to improve health. In other words, changing

  how health funding is spent, rather than mere cost cutting, is key to achieving better value.24

  23 OECD, Towards High Performing Health Systems (Paris: OECD, 2004).

  24 OECD, OECD Health Systems – Measuring and Improving Performance (Paris: OECD,

  2004).

  

   

  Table 18.2. Waiting times for publicly funded patients in Spain (days)

  1992

  2000

  Cataract surgery

  68.0

  47.6

  Cholecystectomy

  103.4

  53.8

  Hernia

  84.6

  48.3

  Prostatectomy

  119.4

  42.7

  Vaginal hysterectomy

  71.9

  52.5

  Knee arthroscopy

  51.4

  53.8

  Hip replacement

  271.4

  59.8

  Knee replacement

  91.3

  63.4

  Varicose veins

  232.8

  50.6

  Source: OECD, Health Care Systems – Lessons from the Reform Experience

  (Paris: OECD, 2003).

  The case for this modified target has been strengthened by the evidence of the possible impact of incentives within primary care-led

  systems. Without shifts in funding as shares of GDP such systems can

  deliver very clear improvements in access and service. The achievements

  in reducing waiting times in Spain between 1992 and 2000 are a clear

  example.

  The OECD attributes most of the decline to the use of financial incentives in achieving waiting time targets which were introduced after 1998.

  A similar approach to financial incentives, allied to expansion in service,

  was adopted in Denmark, leading to a fall in median waiting times for

  cardiac procedures from thirty days in 1997 to fifteen in 2001, a period in

  which waiting times in the UK rose rapidly.

  Within the UK, reform has shown very positive results where it has

  been tried. Key areas where changes adapted from Scandinavia have been

  introduced include the introduction of new financial penalties/incentives

  for reducing delayed discharge and the choice programme for cardiac and

  other surgery in London.

  Since local councils have faced cost penalties in paying for prolonged

  admissions, the numbers of patients staying in hospital unnecessarily are

  now more than 4,000 lower than in 2001. The Secretary of State has said:

  A massive reduction in delayed discharges was the equivalent of adding

  eight extra hospitals to the NHS. In fact more beds were created through

  incentives than the total additional beds planned through extra funding

  (2,500) over the next decade . . . These figures suggest that the introduc-    

  

  tion of the reimbursement scheme seems to have provided the extra incentive we needed to maintain momentum.25

  In London, between 2002 and 2004, 12,500 patients were offered a

  choice of where their treatment should take place and 7,480 accepted it.26

  Among the results have been that:

  • South-east London Treatment Centres in Orpington and Bromley now

  have spare capacity and began advertising for patients from February

  2004.

  • Private hospitals in the area have become concerned about declining

  patient numbers.

  • The National Heart Hospital, bought to increase NHS capacity in

  cardiac surgery, found that it was short of patients because waiting lists

  had been reduced by the choice programme and it had to convert to

  non-surgical uses.

  Thus within a very short time the choice programme was successful in

  reducing waiting times even before new capacity in Treatment Centres

  was introduced. There was similar success with choice in surgery for

  cataracts in the south of England.

  There has also been a tendency to attribute success to funding when it

  should have been attributed to reform. Thus, in coronary and heart

  disease, the government stresses that the fall in the death rate – 41% over

  the last decade – is the result of NHS modernisation. Much of the work in

  introducing the National Service Framework and extending the use of

  statins, however, has been carried out in primary care where spending

  has been rising more slowly. And within secondary care waiting times

  for cardiac surgery have been reduced, mainly as a result of the choice

  programme.

  The National Audit Office has come to a similar conclusion in regard

  to accident and emergency services. Its recent report found that the

  Department of Health had allocated less than £30 million per year to

  improving A&E services compared to an annual spend on those services

  of over £1 billion. Rather than extra funding, A&E departments have

  improved waiting times by developing new working practices, in particular by treating patients with minor injuries quickly rather than making

  them wait until patients with more serious injuries have been treated

  25 Department of Health press release, ‘Dramatic Fall in Delayed Discharges’, 17 May 2004.

  26 Department of Health press release, ‘NHS in London Advertises for Patients’, 4 February

  2004.

  

   

  (‘see and treat’), by giving more clinical responsibility to experienced

  nurses and by improving access to diagnostic services.27

  Within the service for cancer patients, there has certainly been some

  improvement in access and survival for patients with breast cancer. Better

  funding of new drug therapies is likely to have contributed, but research

  in the US has clearly shown that detection of cancer at an earlier stage

  through screening is the most important reason for better survival. The

  successes in improving survival owe more to long-term investment, since

  the 1980s, in what is now one of the world’s most advanced systems for

  population screening, than to funding increases under The NHS Plan. So

  far, indeed, the results of funding increases have been disappointing. A

  survey by the Royal College of Radiologists in 2003 indicated that wa
iting

  times have not improved since 1998, and that only a minority of patients

  are receiving treatment within recommended waiting times.28 A later

  review showed that by 2006 radiotherapy services were only delivering

  61% of the recommended levels of treatment.

  The future of the NHS will be one of great funding pressure. The NHS

  Plan and the following four years have seen the announcement and design

  of future policies and commitments. In the next phase these new policies

  will actually have to be funded. However, the problem is greater than that

  of short-term funding pressure due to the inconsistency between the

  various key policies. The NHS must manage the effects of five key policies:

  • the introduction of competition between providers through standard

  tariffs where money follows the patient;

  • the rising costs of the hospital system through PFI and new staff

  contracts;

  • a range of new providers, including Treatment Centres and Foundation

  Trusts, operating to much more compelling budgetary incentives by

  which they have to increase activity in order to survive;

  • a strong supply response to the new primary care practice contract

  resulting in many more services at a higher cost;

  • commitments to integrated care for chronic illness through Evercare

  and other systems.

  This range of policies results from the gradual shift from central planning towards local initiative. The PFI schemes are the result of central

  27 National Audit Office, Improving Emergency Care in England (London: NAO, 2004).

  28 Royal College of Radiologists, Equipment, Workload and Staffing for Radiotherapy in the

  UK 1997–2002 (London: Royal College of Radiologists, 2003).

      

  

  Table 18.3. The policy framework to 2010

  Policy

  Comment

  National tariffs

  Full introduction in 2007. Paid at standard rates

  with gainers (costs below tariff) and losers.

  New consultant

  Long-term costs (improved lifetime pay and leave

  contract and Agenda

  allowances) will be greater than immediate costs.

  for Change

  PFI schemes

  New providers

  First wave of contracts will be ending in 2010.

  Treatment Centres and Foundation Trusts with

  room to expand activities (such as Royal Marsden

  and Bradford) will be gainers under the national

  tariff.

  The new GMS contract

 

‹ Prev