The Age of Global Warming: A History

Home > Other > The Age of Global Warming: A History > Page 26
The Age of Global Warming: A History Page 26

by Rupert Darwall


  Then there is the respective status of the scientific knowledge of ozone-layer depletion and global warming. Although the causes of stratospheric ozone depletion had not been proven, certain chemicals had been demonstrated to destroy ozone in laboratory tests under conditions comparable to those in the stratosphere. By comparison, Reinstein observes, the science concerning global climate is extremely complex. Many different layers of the atmosphere must be analysed, many different physical and chemical reactions; the role of clouds, oceans, land masses, vegetation must all be taken into account, as well as complex interactions with radiation from the sun and other parts of space.[5]

  The 1992 Climate Change Convention was adopted on the basis of the precautionary principle, Article 3.3 speaking of the need for the parties to take ‘precautionary measures’. Subsequently the official scientific consensus on global warming hardened with the IPCC’s 1995 Second Assessment Report. ‘The balance of evidence suggests that there is a discernible human influence on global climate,’ although the IPCC acknowledged scientists’ limited ability to quantify the effect because the expected ‘signal’ was still emerging from the noise of natural variability (another way of saying the signal hadn’t unambiguously emerged).[6]

  Even if the scientific uncertainties could be resolved, there was a gulf separating the respective economic cases for the Montreal Protocol and the Kyoto Protocol. In 2007 Cass Sunstein, a law professor at the University of Chicago who subsequently became President Obama’s head of the White House office of information and regulatory affairs, compared the two. Sunstein’s analysis focused on the differences between the ratios of perceived benefits to costs flowing from policies to reverse the depletion of the ozone layer and to slow down global warming, especially for the United States as the world’s largest emitter of CFCs and carbon dioxide. These differences helped explain and drove the differing assessments of national interest, the response of consumers and the role of powerful private actors, Sunstein argued.[7]

  The conclusion was stark. Of all the countries in the world, the US was expected to gain the most from the Montreal Protocol and lose the most from the Kyoto Protocol. The perceived costs of complying with Kyoto were $313 billion higher than the costs of Montreal while the perceived benefits of Kyoto were some $3,562 billion lower than the perceived benefits of Montreal.[8] Put another way, each $1 billion spent complying with Kyoto Protocol was estimated to yield $37 million in benefits.[9] By contrast, each $1 billion spent on complying with the Montreal Protocol was anticipated to yield $170 billion in benefits.[10] For the world as a whole, Montreal was estimated to produce net benefits greater than $900 billion.[11] Kyoto, on the other hand, was expected to generate negative net benefits of $119 billion to $242 billion (the band reflects different treatments of the money spent by the US buying other countries’ excess emissions allowances).[12]

  According to Sunstein, the difference in the cost benefit assessments of the two was corroborated by differences in consumer behaviour. These in turn drove political and business incentives. Vivid warnings about the consequences for human health of CFCs and the trivial costs to consumers of mitigating the risk led Americans to cut purchases of aerosol sprays by more than half. Politicians responded quickly. Who would want to run for election in the Sunbelt on a platform in effect favouring skin cancer for light-skinned people? In 1978, Congress banned the use of CFCs as an aerosol propellant. After DuPont developed HCFCs as viable (and profitable) substitutes for CFCs, businesses followed, pledging to phase out CFCs and lobbying for international controls.*

  Given their comparative advantage over foreign competitors, American businesses could expect to benefit from global moves that generated higher demand for replacements for CFCs. ‘If environmentally unfriendly products are unpopular in the market, industry is likely to respond with safer substitutes.’[13] Again, the contrast with global warming is telling. Despite the enormous media coverage of global warming, if judged by their actions as consumers, Americans do not rate climate change as a serious risk compared to the benefits they derive from the burning of fossil fuels. ‘Contrary to their behaviour in the context of ozone layer depletion, American consumers and voters are now putting little pressure on either markets or officials,’ Sunstein observed.[14]

  To Sunstein, US leadership in obtaining international agreement to cut CFC emissions conforms to the model of a global hegemon providing public goods because it benefited from doing so.[15]

  How does Kyoto fit this model?

  Not very well. Insofar as there were any benefits accruing to the US from complying with Kyoto, they were a fraction of the costs. Although the Clinton administration pledged to reduce emissions by seven per cent compared to eight per cent for the European Union, it was vastly more challenging for the US. The 1990 base year chosen for the Kyoto Protocol was the trough of recession in America, which occurred in 1992 for Europe. In that period, US carbon dioxide emissions rose by 1.3 per cent. In Europe, thanks to recession and the implosion of the former communist economies, emissions fell by nearly five per cent.[16]

  Special factors affected Europe’s two largest emitters which had nothing to do with policies to reduce their carbon dioxide emissions. Helmut Kohl’s Germany was one of the most strenuous in demanding deep emissions cuts, but its approach was based on extraordinarily shallow analysis. After the 1988 Toronto conference had called for developed countries to cut emissions by twenty per cent by 2005, a German study team concluded that the goal was under-ambitious.[17] In early 1990, Kohl asked the BMU, the federal ministry with responsibility for the environment, to prepare a carbon dioxide reduction target.

  After only four weeks looking at the issue, the ministry concluded that a 30.5 per cent reduction was feasible. In June, the government adopted a twenty-five per cent target compared to 1987 levels for West Germany. The target for the former West Germany was reaffirmed in November, the government stating that it expected larger reductions from the former East Germany.[18] It proved wildly optimistic. Although German carbon dioxide emissions fell in twelve of the fifteen years from 1990 to 2005, at the end of the period they were 17.7 per cent below 1990 levels, half the fall coming in the first two years after reunification.[19]

  For Britain, the speed of its fall in carbon dioxide emissions was in response to a major policy error in privatising the electricity industry. The original idea had been to create a power generating duopoly so the larger company could own the country’s nuclear power stations. Preparations for privatisation revealed what many economists and environmental groups had long argued – after taking into account decommissioning costs, nuclear power was fundamentally uneconomic. The nuclear power stations were dropped from the initial privatisation package, but the generating duopoly was preserved. To provide some competitive pressure, the electricity regulator encouraged local electricity distributors to build their own gas-fired power stations by letting them earn temporary super-profits from vertical integration. According to Dieter Helm, the leading authority on the British energy industry, ‘The consequence was that gas came on faster than would have been dictated by competitive markets, and the coal industry contracted more quickly.’[20] Together with the effect of a sharp recession at the beginning of the 1990s, the switch from coal to natural gas helped Britain’s emissions to fall by nearly seven per cent from 1990 to 1997.[21]

  As the negotiations progressed, the EU proposed their members share the British and German reductions under an EU ‘bubble’, even though they were simultaneously arguing that other countries should be held to flat rate reductions. Yet the high cost of meeting Kyoto’s seven per cent cut for America was not the decisive factor behind America’s non-ratification of Kyoto. The fundamental reason lay in the architecture of the Protocol, which followed the ground plan of the convention. This divided the world into two, with developed nations listed in Annex I of the convention. Non-Annex I nations therefore comprised the rest of the world – the
least developed, oil-rich exporters, successfully industrialised and the world’s fastest growing economies.

  At the convention’s first COP in Berlin in the spring of 1995, the parties agreed that the commitments of the Annex I parties needed to be strengthened. As a condition for allowing the process to proceed, the G77 plus China stipulated that no new commitments should be introduced for non-Annex I parties. This agreement was incorporated into the Berlin Mandate, which defined the objectives and parameters for the negotiations that resulted in the Kyoto Protocol.

  At COP2 in Geneva the following July, Tim Wirth, now serving as undersecretary of state for global affairs, announced that the Clinton administration would be urging Annex I countries to negotiate ‘realistic, verifiable and binding targets’ to reverse the trend of rising greenhouse gas emissions. ‘This is a big deal,’ Wirth told the New York Times.[22]

  It certainly was. A year later, the US Senate adopted the Byrd-Hagel resolution by ninety-five to zero; America should not sign any protocol which imposed limits on Annex I parties unless it also imposed specific, timetabled commitments on non-Annex I countries within the same compliance period. In some respects, the resolution represented the Senate taking a second look at the convention it had ratified less than five years earlier by a similar margin as it had adopted Byrd-Hagel. The principle of ‘common but differentiated responsibilities’ – the first of the convention’s five principles – and the bifurcation between Annex I parties and the rest of the world were central to the convention’s ground plan.

  There was always a high risk of the Annex I bifurcation becoming unbridgeable, as the convention did not provide an automatic mechanism by which non-Annex I countries could or should graduate to Annex I. However it contained two provisions that might have served as a basis for bridging the divide. Article 4.2(f) stipulated that by the end of 1998, a future COP should have reviewed available information ‘with a view to taking decisions’ on the matter, so long as any move into Annex I was with the approval of the party concerned.[23] The provision was essentially stillborn, only being used to remove Turkey, considered a developed country for the purposes of global warming, from the Annex II donor countries, which mirrors Annex I, so Turkey remained in Annex I but does not have Annex II donor obligations. The second provision, Article 4.2(d), required the periodic review of adequacy of the commitments of Annex I and non-Annex I parties. As we shall see, the fate of this provision provides one of the most telling pieces of evidence as to the attitude of the developing world to the global warming negotiations.

  The effect of the Berlin Mandate was not to change the structure of the convention, but to build a wall around the existing Annex I parties and thereby institutionalise the division between North and South. To date, only Malta has crossed this new Berlin Wall, and that was because it had joined the EU (Cyprus, the only other non-Annex I country to become a member of the EU, so far has not done so). If there was any issue that risked triggering the collapse of negotiations at Kyoto, it was in response to any attempt to fragment or erode the solidarity of the G77 plus China on this issue.

  By contrast, the Montreal Protocol avoided this by having a unified ground plan based on objective criteria. While bearing in mind the developmental needs of developing countries, to use the words of the Montreal Protocol’s preamble, there is no list of countries subject to quantitative limits; the annexes simply list the various categories of controlled gases. Developing countries are subject to the full control regime while capping their per capita consumption of ozone depleting gases. In the case of CFCs, developing countries which consume less than 0.3 kg per capita of CFCs a year are granted a grace period of ten years ‘in order to meet its basic domestic needs’ before having to comply with the full rigour of the Protocol’s controls, as long as they keep their per capita consumption below 0.3 kg a year.[24]

  Thus the Montreal Protocol provides a tough, universal regime with powerful sanctions for compliance. The bifurcated regime adopted in the 1992 climate change convention and developed further by the Kyoto Protocol can only be judged superior to the Montreal Protocol if the principal objective is assumed not to be the reduction of greenhouse gas emissions.

  History helps explain why such divergent approaches were taken. The Montreal Protocol was negotiated between 1985 and 1987, in the brief period after the rise of Mikhail Gorbachev and before the formal adoption of the doctrine of sustainable development in 1988. Agreement on the final text was secured five months after publication of the Brundtland Report in April 1987. By contrast, the climate change regime is an offspring of the doctrine of sustainable development, a term that does not appear anywhere in the Montreal Protocol, and its fusion of First World environmentalism and the Third World’s demand for the New International Economic Order.

  Of the world’s top ten per capita carbon dioxide emitters in 2000, six are outside Annex I, including the top three, Qatar (with per capita emissions three times those of the US and nearly six times the average of the developed world), the United Arab Emirates and Kuwait.[25] Neither is per capita GDP a criterion for inclusion. By 2009 for example, non-Annex I South Korea had per capita GDP of $23,407, just $278 less than the EU’s at $23,685.[26]

  Instead of being based on objective criteria, the Annex I dividing line closely follows the 1980 Brandt Line, purportedly delineating the unbridgeable chasm dividing the rich North from the poor South. Thus Annex I countries comprise the old OECD (i.e., excluding Mexico, Chile, Israel and South Korea, which were not OECD members at the time) plus the countries of the former Soviet bloc, but excluding the Soviet Union’s Asian republics, such as Turkmenistan and Kazakhstan. The resulting North-South demarcation, as carved in stone in global warming agreements, is a product of history. It has a political explanation, but no objective economic justification.

  With the Montreal Protocol, developing countries had not engaged early in the process or en bloc. After it came into force in 1989, developing countries asserted their need for new and additional transfers, agreement being reached at the London ozone conference in July 1990, when the Chinese and Indian delegations announced that they were recommending that their countries ratify the protocol. Coming late to the party had a cost, because the developed nations, led by the US, had already settled the Protocol’s main terms. They weren’t going to make the same mistake twice. In 1989, Brazil and Mexico pressed for increased developing country representation in negotiations to tackle global warming, creating a Special Committee on the Participation of Developing Countries. The following year, the UN resolution establishing the INC specified that it should be open to all member states.

  Putting developing countries on an equal footing had profound implications for the conduct of the negotiations as well as their outcome. The Montreal Protocol was negotiated by around thirty countries. Typically the climate change COPs have been attended by one hundred and fifty or more countries and more than one thousand, three hundred delegates.[27] Progress is achieved through UN-style consensus rather than majority voting, meaning that there must be no stated or formal objections to a decision.[28]

  Given all these constraints, to have produced a treaty signed by over one hundred and ninety nations was the result of a diplomatic tour de force. Michael Oppenheimer, an astrophysicist subsequently specialising in atmospheric physics and chemistry, was in Kyoto as science adviser to the Environmental Defence Fund. Al Gore, Oppenheimer said, was the only person with the history, understanding and reputation to bring it together. ‘If this fails, a large part of the blame falls on the administration.’[29] He was wrong on both counts.

  There was one person who could and did bring the negotiations to a successful conclusion and that was Raúl Estrada-Oyuela, the Argentine diplomat who chaired the negotiations over a period of thirty-two months. The resulting agreement was, Estrada wrote two years later, the ‘best compromise the international community was able to reach at that time’.[30] It was a
diplomatic accomplishment of the highest order. ‘I thought Raúl did a strong, credible job in a most challenging negotiation,’ Tim Wirth told the author.[31]

  To have blamed Gore if the conference had broken up without an agreement or for its failure to produce a treaty which met the requirements of the Byrd-Hagel resolution would also have been unfair. But it wasn’t in the interests of NGOs like the Environmental Defence Fund to point their finger in the direction of the South, but at America and its most prominent environmentalist.

  At a symbolic level, though, Gore invited the charge because he had made it himself: Western civilisation was the root cause of the environmental crisis. Nature was in crisis because Western man was sick. ‘Ecology and the human spirit’ is the somewhat Germanic sounding subtitle of Earth in the Balance, in which Gore set out these and other thoughts. At other times, Gore conceded that Western man might not be wholly to blame. Thinking about human beings and the environment led him to pose the biggest environmental question of all. Had God made a mistake when giving mankind dominion over the earth?[32]

  Gore’s ecological philosophy brought together an American tradition of environmentalism, extending from Thoreau and Muir, with crankier elements imported from Europe, notably Schumacher. What made Gore unique was that no ecologist before him had attained high political office, let alone being a heartbeat away from the presidency of the United States. The harsh criticism Gore directed at the preceding and succeeding administrations contrasts with the Clinton administration’s performance with respect to the Kyoto Protocol, the subject of the next two chapters.

 

‹ Prev