How to Spend $50 Billion to Make the World a Better Place

Home > Other > How to Spend $50 Billion to Make the World a Better Place > Page 4
How to Spend $50 Billion to Make the World a Better Place Page 4

by Bjorn Lomborg


  P1: JzG

  0521866790c01

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  15:28

  CLIMATE CHANGE

  OPPONENTS’ VIEWS

  In his challenge paper, William Cline paints a picture of

  severe long-term economic damage that would result from

  climate change if mankind does not take decisive action

  to reduce greenhouse gas emissions in the near future.

  His preferred option is the introduction of aggressive carbon taxes which would rise steadily over the next two to

  300 years. Robert Mendlesohn, in his opposition paper,

  takes issue with the logic and analysis that leads Cline to these conclusions.

  In Mendlesohn’s view, Cline makes the mistake of

  proposing very costly (and economically damaging) strate-

  gies in the short term to tackle potential problems that

  might result from the action of future generations. He

  thinks it would be fairer for those costs to be borne by those generations causing the problem, if they so choose.

  Economists use a process called discounting to compare

  costs and benefits over time. This accounts for the common-sense fact that it is only worthwhile spending money now if it produces future benefits greater than the interest which could be gained by saving it. Because Cline believes that

  climate damage in the far future is so important, he sets

  14

  P1: JzG

  0521866790c01

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  15:28

  Climate Change

  15

  an artificially low discount rate so that the cost of damage appears large in present-day terms.

  Another flaw is his reliance on older studies for esti-

  mates. More recently, there is systematic evidence from the literature that likely climate damage had previously been

  overestimated, since studies had failed to allow for adap-

  tation and climate benefits. For example, countries in the polar regions would receive large benefits from warming,

  those in mid-latitudes would benefit as long as the aver-

  age temperature rise was less than 2.5◦C, and only tropical and sub-tropical regions would suffer short-term harm to

  the degree previously suggested. Overall, benefits of global warming are likely to outweigh damage until the rise is

  greater than 2.5◦C, and even then the net damage would

  be far smaller than originally thought.

  Such reduced impacts imply that fossil fuel use would

  not need to be cut as drastically as Cline suggests, and that carbon taxes should be much lower. These would start at

  only $1–2 per ton, rising to $10–20 per ton by 2100. This

  does not take account of the concerns about potentially

  catastrophic events such as shutting down the thermoha-

  line circulation in the Atlantic, but Mendelsohn believes it is unrealistic to link current emissions to such hypothetical events.

  He also argues that emissions of greenhouse gases

  should be controlled in the same way as any other pollutant: by the use of tradable permits. Companies can be issued

  with permits to emit a certain amount of carbon dioxide;

  if they release less, they can sell part of their allowance. A further major abatement policy that Cline does not cover

  P1: JzG

  0521866790c01

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  15:28

  16

  How to Spend $50 Billion to Make the World a Better Place is carbon sequestration: removal of carbon dioxide from

  the atmosphere, for example, by growing trees. Mendlesohn

  believes that an optimal forest management program can

  be constructed that could account for one-third of the total abatement. This would reduce the level of emissions tax

  needed.

  Based on the more recent evidence, none of the options

  proposed by Cline would be cost-effective, in Mendlesohn’s view: Only the much more modest proposals of carbon

  tax rates between $1 and $20 per ton for the next cen-

  tury have a benefit-cost ratio greater than one. In contrast, Cline’s “optimal” program would yield a benefit-cost ratio of only 0.07 by 2100: $100 of cost would produce only $7 of benefit.

  In summary, Mendlesohn argues for a much less dra-

  conian approach to climate change policy, and takes a

  far more optimistic view of mankind’s ability to learn,

  adapt, and find better solutions. He proposes that com-

  mitments should only be made for what is definitely

  intended to be done in the near term, and that the policy

  should then be reviewed every decade in the light of new

  evidence.

  Alan Manne, in his opposition paper, also agrees that

  Cline has overstated the immediacy of the problems pre-

  sented by climate change. In his view, dealing with poverty and disease in developing countries warrants much higher

  priority. He criticizes Cline’s arguments for an optimal carbon tax. He also objects to Cline considering an even more risk-averse solution (the so-called “value-at-risk” approach)

  P1: JzG

  0521866790c01

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  15:28

  Climate Change

  17

  that appears to justify yet higher carbon taxes. This is based on a highly pessimistic view of current uncertainties, many of which will be resolved in the future.

  Manne’s main concern, which he shares with Mendle-

  sohn, is that Cline’s discounting strategy is unduly alarmist.

  He uses an unrealistic economic analysis to achieve the

  result he wants.

  Unlike Mendlesohn, Manne includes in his analysis fac-

  tors such as impact on human health, species loss, and

  catastrophic risks such as shut-down of the Atlantic thermohaline circulation (so-called non-market damage). Indeed,

  in his view the market damages (losses to agriculture and

  fisheries, for example) that are the usual basis of economic analysis are not the principal reason to be concerned about climate change. How much individual countries would be

  prepared to pay to avoid climate damage depends on a

  number of factors, but will depend largely on the estimated benefit-cost ratio.

  In Manne’s opinion, Cline’s use of an unrealistically

  low discount rate inevitably means that high carbon taxes, designed to force a rapid reduction in the use of fossil fuels, is the only reason this aggressive approach appears to be

  cost-effective.

  A more measured, market oriented strategy would still

  limit temperature rise to 2.5◦C, but would delay costly

  abatement measures, which a more prosperous future

  world might show a greater willingness to pay. In contrast to Cline’s aggressive carbon tax rates, starting at $300 per ton, Manne’s approach suggests a near-term optimal tax

  P1: JzG

  0521866790c01

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  15:28

  18

  How to Spend $50 Billion to Make the World a Better Place of $12 per ton. This is higher than Mendelsohn’s $1–2 per

  ton, but nevertheless these two very different approaches

  still come to essentially the same conclusio
n: Cline’s highly expensive, social engineering approach is not justified. Both authors put far more faith in mankind’s ability to adapt and develop appropriately flexible solutions.

  P1: JzG

  0521866790c02

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  15:35

  ANNE MILLS AND SAM SHILLCUTT1

  2

  Communicable Diseases

  The challenge of communicable disease

  The second half of the twentieth century saw enormous

  improvements in health across the whole world. Indeed,

  life expectancy in developing countries has increased faster than in the industrialized world, albeit from a lower

  baseline. People in many developing countries have life

  expectancies close to those in more advanced economies,

  but there is now a big gap between them and another group

  of countries, mainly in sub-Saharan Africa (SSA), where

  high mortality persists.

  In 2002, there were 57 million deaths worldwide. Of

  these, 20% were children under five, and 98% of these childhood deaths occurred in developing countries. Communica-

  ble diseases represent seven out of the top 10 causes of child deaths in developing countries, and account for around 60%

  of all such deaths: more than 6 million deaths annually.

  A further problem in developing countries is premature

  1 Health Economics and Financing Programme, London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine.

  19

  P1: JzG

  0521866790c02

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  15:35

  20

  How to Spend $50 Billion to Make the World a Better Place mortality of adults (15–59), which represents 30% of all

  deaths, compared to only 20% in developed economies.

  As ever, it is the poorest in these countries who suffer

  disproportionately.

  Non-smokers in the richest countries have a lower risk

  of dying throughout their life than other population cat-

  egories. Deaths in excess of the rate in this category can be considered avoidable, and certain sectors of developing country societies, particularly infants and young women,

  are disproportionately affected. Around 90% of these avoidable deaths are caused by communicable diseases. The tools to tackle these have been employed to good effect in the

  world’s richest countries, but the challenge is now to make them available to the world’s poorest people.

  In this chapter, the focus is on three major opportu-

  nities to combat communicable disease out of the many

  possibilities:

  r Malaria control.

  r HIV/AIDS control.

  r Scaled-up basic health services.

  Of course, these are to some extent interdependent, but we examine them separately for clarity.

  Assessing the opportunities

  Health has both direct and indirect effects on a coun-

  try’s economy; direct through the impact of ill health on

  current productivity, and indirect via the size and qual-

  ity of the labor force as determined by such factors as

  P1: JzG

  0521866790c02

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  15:35

  Communicable Diseases

  21

  Higher fertility

  Higher

  Labour force

  and

  dependency

  reduced by

  child mortality

  ratio

  mortality and

  early retirement

  Lower

  per capita

  income

  Labour

  Adult

  Child

  productivity

  Illness and

  illness

  reduced

  malnutrition

  Reduced access

  Child

  to natural

  malnutrition

  resources and

  global economy

  Less schooling

  Reduced

  and impaired

  investment in

  inactive capacity

  physical capital

  Figure 2.1. Channels through which illness reduces income

  Source: Ruger, Jamison and Bloom (2001).

  mortality, fertility, and intellectual capacity. The drain on economic performance through ill health can be reversed

  by appropriate interventions; for example, up to 1.7% of

  annual economic growth in East Asia between 1965 and

  1990 (about half the total GDP increase for the period) has been attributed to massive improvements in public health.

  Some analysts even have argued that such health improve-

  ments have contributed at least as much to economic devel-

  opment as have innovation and expansion in goods and

  services.

  The costs of poor health across communities can

  be assessed by both micro- and macroeconomic studies.

  P1: JzG

  0521866790c02

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  15:35

  22

  How to Spend $50 Billion to Make the World a Better Place Microeconomic studies examine the effect of disease at a

  household level, but they tend to underestimate the full

  economic impact of poor health. This is partly because

  communities adopt coping mechanisms such as labor sub-

  stitution within the family, liquidating assets, and increased birth-rates. Furthermore, because the state of health usually affects an entire community, there are no unaffected

  households with which to make direct comparisons, nor

  good ways of accurately assessing the value of alternative activities for which labor is unavailable.

  Macroeconomic studies, in contrast, compare the effects

  of disease on the economies of different countries. Such

  studies attempt to capture the full, wide-ranging effects

  of ill health, but there is much less data of this type

  available.

  Most studies of particular interventions have analyzed

  the data in terms of cost effectiveness rather than cost-

  benefit ratios, calculating the cost-per-life saved or disability averted. To draw on this data to produce a cost-benefit analysis, a monetary value must be placed on human life.

  This value will vary with the approach taken and assump-

  tions made, introducing a degree of subjectivity into the

  final analysis.

  In this chapter, these cost effectiveness studies and other relevant work have been used as a basis for calculating costs and benefits of the three opportunities being considered. No attempt has been made to extrapolate results for a particular country to a wider area, but the various pieces of evidence taken together give a sense of the overall cost-benefit balance. To avoid understating benefits, results are adjusted

  P1: JzG

  0521866790c02

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  15:35

  Communicable Diseases

  23

  to Purchasing Power Parity and expressed in 2003 interna-

  tional dollars (Int $).

  A standard discount rate of 3% has been used to cal-

  culate net present values. Simple sensitivity analyses were done to ensure the conclusions were not just valid for a single s
et of assumptions.

  Control of malaria

  Malaria – a parasitic disease spread by the Anopheles mos-

  quito – is transmitted in 103 countries, and is estimated to cause 1–3 million deaths annually. It is now primarily a tropical disease, having been eradicated from North America,

  Europe, and Russia during the twentieth century.

  Malaria is caused by four different species of the Plas-modium parasite. The most dangerous of these predomi-nates in sub-Saharan Africa (SSA), where 90% of malarial

  deaths (and 85% of all infections) occur. There are two types of transmission:

  1. Stable, in which young children are repeatedly infected.

  Those who survive acquire immunity, meaning that

  they are very unlikely to die from the disease as adults

  (although they may have recurrent fevers).

  2. Unstable, where transmission rates are low and immunity does not develop. In this case, malaria epidemics

  occur, and deaths occur amongst all age groups.

  In Africa, about 1 million deaths caused by malaria are

  believed to occur each year, more than three-quarters of

  them children. In SSA, malaria accounts for around 20%

  P1: JzG

  0521866790c02

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  15:35

  24

  How to Spend $50 Billion to Make the World a Better Place of deaths of under-5s. This is a small proportion of the

  total disease burden: 200–450 million cases of malaria are estimated to occur among young children in Africa, and

  there could be in the region of 2 billion cases globally. 3%

  of attacks are characterized as severe, and half of those

  affected die if they do not receive hospital treatment.

  In addition to the direct effects, malaria is an important cause of anemia, interacts with other infectious diseases, and contributes to Low Birth Weight when contracted during pregnancy. As well as its various direct and indirect

  physical effects, malaria is believed to have a significant negative impact on intellectual development.

  Microeconomic impact

  There is evidence of a considerable burden on households

  and governments for prevention and treatment. In Malawi,

  for example, it was estimated that the total annual direct cost of malaria for an average household was $40, representing over 7% of total income. Similar figures have been reported for small farmers in other African countries: 9–

  18% of income in Kenya, and 7–13% in Nigeria. It seems

  quite clear that the burden falls particularly heavily on the poorest in each society.

 

‹ Prev