How to Spend $50 Billion to Make the World a Better Place

Home > Other > How to Spend $50 Billion to Make the World a Better Place > Page 6
How to Spend $50 Billion to Make the World a Better Place Page 6

by Bjorn Lomborg


  Van der Gaag challenges Mills and Shillcutt’s recommen-

  dations for increased spending on health service provisions.

  In his view, there is a very small effect of such spending on health. The more important factors, such as income, education, and access to safe water and sanitation, have been

  P1: JzG

  0521866790c02

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  15:35

  Communicable Diseases

  35

  ignored. This means that the benefit-cost ratio for increased public health care spending is actually far lower than stated.

  He also makes the point that, in most developing coun-

  tries, the vast majority of publicly provided healthcare services are consumed by the better-off and do not reach the

  poor. At the same time, private suppliers are not allowed

  to compete. The seriousness of the disease burden – much

  of it avoidable – is such that all alternatives to the current options should be tried. Costs may be higher, but benefits also may be much greater.

  Evans, in his opposition paper, takes a more favorable

  view of the opportunities that form the basis of the chal-

  lenge paper. However, he casts doubt on some of the figures used in the analysis. In particular, he questions the appropriateness of making comparisons between different inter-

  ventions, since some are based on the impact of health on

  GDP (macroeconomic effect) and some on the estimated

  monetary value of welfare benefits (microeconomic anal-

  ysis). In many cases, health care programs may do little

  for economic growth, and may therefore be rejected. Evans

  believes that analysis based on cost-effectiveness criteria (how much welfare is created for a given input) is more

  reliable and useful for policy makers.

  The Cost Of Illness framework seeks to include all

  direct costs (treatment, transport, etc.) and indirect costs (loss of earnings, etc). However, this leads to an imperfect assessment of the true burden of disease on house-

  holds, and is even more misleading when projected in

  terms of overall GDP loss. Although accurate estimates of

  P1: JzG

  0521866790c02

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  15:35

  36

  How to Spend $50 Billion to Make the World a Better Place monetary costs are difficult to make, the destruction of

  households and the social fabric caused by disease (AIDS

  in particular) is all too real. The effects on labor are also substantial: Life expectancy at birth in Southern Africa was 43 years in 2002, but in the absence of AIDS would have

  been 56.

  Evans agrees with van der Gaag that the challenge paper

  underestimates the costs of AIDS interventions, because it does not take account of treatment costs in countries where the emphasis is on prevention. This would add significantly to the cost. Nevertheless, the benefit-cost ratio is so large that the extra costs would be easily justified.

  Evans also makes the same point as van der Gaag about

  government spending on health: There is little evidence to show that this has a significant impact, whereas money

  spent on health education has much more effect. Although

  not proposing the more radical approach advocated in the

  other opponent paper, he still believes that intense effort is needed to ensure health services can deliver results. One aspect of this is to develop new and better ways for government and non-government sectors to work together and to

  look at new ways of organizing and delivering services.

  There are still large funding gaps to be filled – nearly $4

  billion to treat half the total number of HIV/AIDS sufferers by 2005 – even without dealing with the associated problem of TB. There are additional costs associated with pro-

  viding the basic healthcare infrastructure needed to deliver the potential benefits.

  Evans makes one final point about the ethical dimension

  of using economic analysis to prioritize programs to fight

  P1: JzG

  0521866790c02

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  15:35

  Communicable Diseases

  37

  disease. Implicitly, they value human life in poor countries less than in richer countries. On a global scale, this is likely to focus attention on fighting diseases primarily of the developed world, such as cardiovascular disease, rather than

  scourges such as HIV/AIDS and malaria.

  P1: JzG

  0521866790c02

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  15:35

  38

  P1: JPJ

  0521866790c03

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  15:49

  PAUL COLLIER AND ANKE HOEFFLER1

  3

  The Challenge of Reducing the

  Global Incidence of Civil War

  Introduction and overview

  Although wars between nations have become less common

  in recent decades, the frequency of civil wars around the

  world has increased. These two types of conflict cannot sensibly be analyzed together, so this chapter focuses entirely on reducing the incidence of civil wars.

  Three main approaches are discussed:

  r Conflict prevention.

  r Shortening conflicts.

  r Post-conflict policies.

  Since the post-conflict period actually presents particularly high risks, the biggest opportunity lies in preventing wars from recurring.

  1 Centre for the Study of African Economies, Department of Economics, Oxford University.

  39

  P1: JPJ

  0521866790c03

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  15:49

  40

  How to Spend $50 Billion to Make the World a Better Place The benefits of reducing the incidence of civil war

  Benefits from reducing conflict and war accrue at three distinct levels: national, regional and global.

  Taking the national level first, one clear cost of civil war is a reduction in economic growth. Using a conservative

  estimate, one year of conflict reduces a country’s growth

  rate by 2.2%. Since, on average, each civil conflict lasts for seven years, the economy will be 15% smaller at the end

  of the war than if the war had not taken place. During

  the post-war recovery, even though the economy on aver-

  age grows at an annual rate of more than 1% above the

  norm, it will take roughly 10 years to return to its pre-war growth rates (that is, 17 years after the conflict started).

  21 years after the start of the original war, the GDP has

  returned to the level it would have achieved if no war had occurred. The total economic cost, expressed as a present

  value at the start of the war (using a 5% discount rate),

  is 105% of the GDP at that point. This seems to be a fairly conservative estimate, as a more detailed analysis shows the actual figure to lie in the range 41–305% (90% confidence

  limits).

  The welfare of a country’s population is further reduced

  because of increased military spending during and after

  the war. It is estimated that military spending increases

  by about 1.8
% during the war, and only falls back by 0.5%

  once the conflict has ended. Assuming that this higher level of spending lasts for only 10 years after the conflict, the additional cost (expressed again as present value when the conflict started) is 18% of GDP.

  P1: JPJ

  0521866790c03

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  15:49

  Cost

  Benefit

  Net benefit

  conflict

  Peace-keeping

  forces following

  rnational issues.

  conflict

  Aid following

  goods

  ertified C

  y

  conflicts

  Costs and benefits of conflict opportunities

  **

  Transparenc

  reducing

  of

  e

  benefits

  and

  General increas

  Cost

  in development aid

  5

  0

  3.1.

  -5

  30

  25

  20

  15

  10

  -10

  Billion USD yearly

  *) The costs are difficult to quantify and is largely made up of the opportunity costs by not investing the funds in other inte Figure

  41

  P1: JPJ

  0521866790c03

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  15:49

  42

  How to Spend $50 Billion to Make the World a Better Place In addition, conflict has a severe effect on human health.

  One way of summarizing this effect is to express the cost in terms of Disability Affected Life-Years (DALYs): a measure of the total number of people affected and the period for

  which their disability lasts. An average war causes an estimated 0.5 million DALYs each year. Assuming they decline

  smoothly to zero in the 21st year, and discounting them at 5% as for the direct economic costs, gives a figure of 5 million DALYs as the net present value of health costs when hos-tilities start. If each DALY is valued at $1,000 (roughly the per capita income in many at-risk countries), the economic cost of harm to human health in a typical war is around

  $5 billion.

  At the regional level, analysis shows that the growth rate of neighboring countries not directly involved in the conflict is reduced by 0.9% during the war. If they subsequently recover at the same rate as the conflict country, the additional cost (as a present value at the start of the conflict) is 43% of initial GDP. On average, each country has 2.7 neighbors, so the direct effect of a typical civil war on neighboring countries is 115% of the initial GDP of one country: greater than the direct effect in the conflict country itself.

  There is also an effect on military spending in adjoining

  countries: a neighborhood arms race often ensues. In the

  average case considered so far, a 1% rise in military expenditure in the country at war would increase the average spending of bordering countries by 0.23%. In a typical conflict, that means military spending will increase by 0.4% of GDP

  during the war, and by 0.3% during the post-conflict period: a total net present value of 4.3% of the country’s initial

  P1: JPJ

  0521866790c03

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  15:49

  The Challenge of Reducing the Global Incidence of Civil War 43

  GDP. On average, there are 2.7 neighboring countries; thus the total extra cost of the regional arms race is about 12%

  of one country’s GDP.

  Other costs which are too difficult to quantify are

  incurred both in the country at war and in the region as a whole, including forced migration. With the proviso that the figures so far are therefore underestimated to some degree, the total benefit of averting a single “typical” civil war can be calculated. The various national and regional costs covered so far amount to 250% of initial GDP. The average GDP of

  conflict-affected low-income countries (excluding India and China) just prior to war is $19.7 billion. Therefore, the cost of a single war is around $49 billion. To this we must add $5 billion of health costs, giving a total cost of $54 billion for a single low-income country.

  This is already a significant figure, but in addition there is the “conflict trap”: Countries that have just experienced a civil war are more likely to have further conflict. Looking at the 21 countries in which wars started and ended in the period 1965–99, the risk of conflict over the five years before the war averaged 22.3%, but this rose to 38.6% post-war.

  Over the 15-year period needed for the risk to reach the

  pre-war level again, the additional discounted cost is $10.2

  billion. Thus the total national and regional cost of a single war is more than $64 billion.

  There are additional, global impacts of civil wars, mas-

  sive in scale but difficult to assign a cost to. Three world scourges over the last 30 years have had civil conflicts

  as contributory factors: hard drug production, AIDS, and

  international terrorism.

  P1: JPJ

  0521866790c03

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  15:49

  44

  How to Spend $50 Billion to Make the World a Better Place Based on these estimates (and bearing in mind the

  unquantified but significant global effects of conflict), we can look at the benefits of reducing the number of countries at war at any one time. At present, an average of two civil wars start each year. The net cost of these would be $128 billion. So, an initiative which reduced the chance of a new war by 10%, for example, would generate benefits of

  around $13 billion each year.

  Another class of opportunities are those which shorten

  wars rather than prevent them. The benefit of shortening

  the typical war by one year – from seven to six years – turns out to be surprisingly large: nearly $11 billion. For the average of two new conflicts per year, this would generate benefits of about $22 billion annually. There would also be a one-off gain from shortening the present 17 significant civil conflicts by one year. A discounted value of this figure (comparable to the year-on-year benefit) is around $9 billion, so the total annual benefit of shortening civil wars by one year is over $30 billion.

  Opportunities for conflict prevention

  Analysis shows that a country’s political and social characteristics are much less important than economic factors in determining the risk of war. The three most significant char-acteristics are level of income, its rate of income growth, and the degree of dependence upon primary commodity

  exports.

  Of the two wars that on average start annually, 0.7

  occur in the poor, relatively small countries with no recent

  P1: JPJ

  0521866790c03

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  15:49

  The Challenge of Reducing the Global Incidence of Civil War 45

  history of war (China and India are excluded because or

  their sheer size). Here we look at the benefits of preventing some of these. Post-conflict situations represent a separate opportunity.

  Raising the economic growth rate reduces the risk of

  conflict both directly and by increasing incomes. As a

  point of reference, a 1% increase in annual growth rate

  for a period of 10 years was modeled. For the first five

  years, the model shows a red
uction in the risk of war

  from 13.8% to 12.7% as the average risk of a war break-

  ing out in a poor country with no recent war. During

  the second five-year period, the additional income level

  effect reduces the risk further, to 12.2%. Assuming that the growth rate returns to normal after the 10 year period, the longer term effect of higher income leaves the risk of conflict at 12.7%, as a permanent reduction over the initial

  level.

  In financial terms, the benefit in the first five years is an 8% reduction in the chance of a civil war starting. Since

  each war costs $64 billion, and on average 0.7 start each

  year, the annual benefit is $3.6 billion. In the second five-year period, this gain rises to $5.4 billion annually (a 12%

  reduction in the risk of conflict starting). After 10 years, the annual benefit falls back to $3.6 billion. The present value (discounted at 5%) is around $79 billion. To put this large figure in perspective, remember that this is purely a benefit of conflict reduction, over and above the direct benefits of poverty reduction.

  Two major policy options might deliver these benefits:

  aid and better utilization of income from natural resources.

  P1: JPJ

  0521866790c03

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  15:49

  46

  How to Spend $50 Billion to Make the World a Better Place Aid

  The effect of aid will depend to a large extent on the political and institutional situation. Additional aid as a means to boost growth is also subject to the law of diminishing

  returns. On average, for a single country from the group of 32 poor, relatively small, and generally peaceful states, an extra 2% in aid would raise their annual growth rates by

  only 0.2%. The benefits of aid in terms of conflict reduction would therefore be one-fifth of that from the model of 1%

  additional GDP growth: $16 billion.

  At purchasing power parity rates, the combined GDPs

  of the countries in this group amount to $1,200 billion, so the overall cost of the additional aid amounts to $24 billion annually. The net present value of this over a decade is $195

  billion. This indicates that unselective aid programs are not a cost effective way of reducing conflict: The benefits are less than 10% of the costs. This is not to say that the aid may not be justified; after all, its main purpose is poverty reduction.

  However, conflict reduction should not be expected to be a major outcome.

  Improved governance of income from natural resources

 

‹ Prev