How to Spend $50 Billion to Make the World a Better Place

Home > Other > How to Spend $50 Billion to Make the World a Better Place > Page 13
How to Spend $50 Billion to Make the World a Better Place Page 13

by Bjorn Lomborg

most economists and other commentators. However, there

  is no consensus on how migration might achieve this, with

  strong arguments being made both for and against.

  In 2000, it was estimated that 175 million people – 3%

  of the global population – were migrants who had lived out-side their country of birth or citizenship for a year or more.

  This number had doubled in the previous 25 years, during

  which the world’s population grew by 50%. Most migrants

  move from poorer to richer countries, with about 60% of the total now living in the more developed countries. Although there are many more potential migrants, immigration has

  become a major political issue in receiving countries (for example, European Union Member States). Public opinion

  polls suggest that most residents oppose further immigra-

  tion and support government measures to reduce illegal or

  irregular migration.

  Most economists welcome migration from lower- to

  higher-wage countries, because it uses resources more efficiently and maximizes production. The global economic

  gain is the sum of net income gains of individual migrants, plus a small bonus for receiving countries. It was estimated in 1984 that world GDP could more than double if

  free migration was allowed, adding between $5 trillion and $16 trillion to the 1977 figure of $8 trillion. The global economy has now grown to over $30 trillion, making potential

  gains today far greater. With such potential gains, the benefit from even partial liberalization of labor flows could benefit the world economy far more than trade liberalization.

  For countries receiving migrant workers, the overall eco-

  nomic impacts are clearly positive, albeit there will be some

  P1: OyK

  0521866790c07

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  17:16

  Population and Migration

  115

  Table 7.1. Europe and Africa, demography,

  1800–2050

  Share of world population %

  1800

  2000

  2050

  Africa

  8

  13

  20

  Europe

  20

  12

  7

  World pop. (bn)

  1

  6

  9

  losers who must be compensated. For countries that are

  net senders of migrants, the situation is less clear-cut. So, although the global economy and individual migrants may

  benefit, sending countries may find their economic development held back by the loss of talented, educated citizens. In a worst-case scenario, migration may actually cause further divergence of per capita incomes.

  There are clear arguments for developed countries, with

  aging populations and fewer young workers, to use immi-

  gration to stabilize work forces. Many developing countries are happy to export some of their excess labor to increase remittances and acquire new skills. However, managing

  migration optimally for the benefit of all parties is more difficult.

  Migration is driven by differences. As economic differ-

  ences widen, developing country populations continue to

  grow, and transport becomes cheaper and easier, migration

  pressures will increase. As well as the basic gap in GDP, the continued drift of labor away from agriculture (the world’s major employer) creates a larger pool of willing migrants.

  This is partly a result of trade barriers to agricultural produce, which reduce farm employment in poor countries.

  At the same time, there is a demand for migrant labor to

  P1: OyK

  0521866790c07

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  17:16

  116 How to Spend $50 Billion to Make the World a Better Place work on the subsidized, protected farms in industrialized

  countries.

  Ethnic or security differences also drive migration. Con-

  flict and the creation of new nations in the old Communist bloc have caused population shifts and contributed to the

  flow of migrants, for example.

  Assessing the opportunities

  Many countries receiving migrants are attempting to

  manage immigration by discouraging potential migrants

  through tighter controls and restriction of benefits. How-

  ever, this is not an optimal solution.

  Three opportunities are assessed in this chapter, all of

  which could be implemented in the next 5 to 15 years. These would each raise the benefits and reduce the costs of migration, most of which would probably occur in any case. In

  brief, these are:

  r Active selection systems to allow in those foreigners

  who are most likely to succeed. This would reduce fears

  of immigration and allow wider entry channels to be

  opened for skilled workers and professionals.

  r Widening legal entry channels for unskilled guest work-

  ers, together with encouragement to return to their

  countries of origin. This would provide temporary labor

  without permanent settlement.

  r Using the 3 R’s of migration – recruitment, remittances, and returns – to promote economic convergence over

  time.

  P1: OyK

  0521866790c07

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  17:16

  Population and Migration

  117

  The overall goal is to create a world in which migration is unnecessary because sufficient opportunity exists at home.

  The majority of people do not migrate, and they will only

  enjoy higher incomes if their countries prosper. The chal-

  lenge is to ensure that the migration of the exceptional few also improves conditions for those who stay behind.

  Opportunity 1: Active selection procedures

  for migrants

  Whereas migration at one time was a difficult, expensive,

  and usually permanent process, the situation today is much more fluid. Migrants now select their destinations and often adjust to long-term resident status after entering on a temporary basis. This adjustment process can be difficult and frustrating for them, and the ambiguity of status of many

  arrivals often leads to the perception or fear of excessive immigration in the host country. Active selection procedures could improve this situation, for the benefit of all concerned.

  We have already seen that the net economic effect

  of immigration to industrialized countries is positive but small. More migration might be tolerated by the host country’s native residents if those migrants who are likely to generate maximum economic benefits to the destination

  country are selected. This is the approach successfully

  adopted in Canada, which uses a points-based decision

  system covering factors such as education and language

  skills. The country has continuing high levels of immigra-

  tion (approximately a quarter of a million people annually

  P1: OyK

  0521866790c07

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  17:16

  118 How to Spend $50 Billion to Make the World a Better Place into a population of 32 million) and significant public sat-isfaction with the policy.

  Alternatively, demand-based systems can be adopted, so

  that employers select migrants they believe best suited for jobs on offer. This inevit
ably creates tensions between companies wishing to employ foreigners and the need to pro-

  tect local workers. To ensure the local labor pool is properly searched, employers could be required to pay a fee to employ migrants.

  There are two potential downsides to selection pro-

  cedures:

  1. The already high costs of curbing unwanted and unlaw-

  ful immigration may rise, to ensure that all immigration

  is properly managed and controls are not bypassed. In

  2002, Canada, Germany, the Netherlands, the UK, and

  the USA collectively spent at least $17 billion to enforce immigration law and care for asylum seekers (about

  two-thirds of the amount they spent on overseas aid).

  2. Selecting the brightest and best from developing coun-

  tries could increase inequality and migration pressures.

  Some compensatory mechanism such as exit taxes or

  continued taxation of migrants by their countries of ori-

  gin might alleviate this.

  Bearing in mind these provisos, increased immigration of

  well-educated, productive workers to developed countries

  could help to stabilize their work forces and pension sys-

  tems. Resistance from the native populations is likely to

  decrease as these benefits become apparent. There is also

  P1: OyK

  0521866790c07

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  17:16

  Population and Migration

  119

  a plausible argument that a certain level of “brain drain”

  would be beneficial for developing countries. If people

  believe that migration could increase their returns from

  education, more people will work for higher qualifications, and only a proportion of them will emigrate. The pool of

  well-educated nationals will increase even as the brain drain continues.

  Although managed migration can be beneficial for all

  parties, it is not always so. At one end of the spectrum,

  migration of IT specialists from India has contributed to

  a virtuous circle of increased technical education and the growth of a significant computer services industry in India itself. At the other end, emigration of doctors and nurses from South Africa has contributed to a continuing decline

  in the number of healthcare professionals available at a time of increasing need.

  Developing countries, led by India, want to see liber-

  alization of the temporary movement of workers (initially

  professionals, later unskilled) on a global basis. The mechanism for this in the long run would be a visa issued under the General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS, part of

  the World Trade Organisation).

  Opportunity 2: Guest worker policies

  Alongside the managed immigration of highly skilled work-

  ers, guest worker programs aim to add mostly unskilled

  workers temporarily to the labor forces of developed coun-

  tries. They usually do so-called “3D” jobs (dirty, dangerous, and difficult) for which local labor is not available.

  P1: OyK

  0521866790c07

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  17:16

  120 How to Spend $50 Billion to Make the World a Better Place However, such programs generally have not been a complete success. They have led to both labor market distortions (where employers rely on a continued supply of immigrant

  labor) and dependence (when migrants and their families

  depend long-term on earnings from foreign jobs). There

  has been little large-scale resumption of the process in

  recent years, but if better ways could be found to manage

  guest workers, there would be benefits for both workers and employers.

  In the 1960s, millions of guest workers from Southern

  Europe and North Africa were employed temporarily in

  Western Europe and were regarded as hardworking. How-

  ever, when recruitment stopped in 1973–74, many unem-

  ployed workers chose not to return to their countries of

  origin. It became easier for new arrivals to receive welfare benefits than get jobs, and migrants began to be viewed by many native residents as a drain on society.

  New guest worker programs set up in the 1990s were

  much more focused, targeting single groups such as com-

  puter programmers or farm laborers. At the same time,

  there are now far more irregular foreign workers in

  developed countries. They can be encouraged into short-

  term legal employment by appropriate tax and subsidy

  regimes.

  The labor market distortion inherent in large-scale guest

  worker schemes can be reduced by appropriate use of

  employer-paid taxes and fees. Dependence can be tackled

  by use of incentives such as repayment of migrant workers’

  social security payments when they return to their countries of origin.

  P1: OyK

  0521866790c07

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  17:16

  Population and Migration

  121

  Significant expansion of temporary worker migra-

  tion still presents challenges. In particular, enforcement becomes a major burden, especially when some sectors have

  large numbers of illegal workers. One solution is “earned

  legalization,” whereby irregular workers can earn legal status by registering and completing employment and tax

  requirements.

  Although economic incentives can help host countries

  to manage temporary migrants, their effect is not always

  predictable. For example, migrant families were encour-

  aged to leave Germany in the early 1980s by the offer of

  a departure bonus of up to $5,000 and repayment of their

  social security contributions. Between 1982 and 1984–5,

  there was a net loss of 300,000 of the then 4.7 million foreigners, but it was concluded afterward that the majority

  of foreigners who took the departure bonus would have left in any case. Of course, from the perspective of returnees, the bonus was a significant benefit, but apparently not an incentive.

  Detailed examination of the economic impact on the

  USA as a host country showed that workers who competed

  with migrants tended to move away from the area, dissipat-

  ing the impact across the country. While the average wage

  reduction due to immigration over the 1980–2000 period

  was 3.2%, this rose to almost 9% for US-born workers who

  had not completed high school.

  In summary, making the transition from the current

  widespread employment of illegal workers to a world of

  legal migrants is a very difficult challenge given growing international inequality.

  P1: OyK

  0521866790c07

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  17:16

  122 How to Spend $50 Billion to Make the World a Better Place Opportunity 3: Migration for development

  Development should reduce economically motivated migra-

  tion by eliminating its root causes. Migration can speed

  up this process if the 3Rs of recruitment, remittances, and returns accelerate economic growth in the country of origin. However, the current impacts of migration are less clear in poor countries than in receiving
countries.

  Recruitment of skilled professionals from developing

  countries could reduce economic growth in these coun-

  tries. However, remittances both from both skilled and

  unskilled migrants, and encouragement of returns, can

  be managed to promote rather than hinder economic

  growth.

  Remittances can be maximized if developing countries

  set realistic exchange rates and adopt economic policies

  likely to foster growth. These remittances more than dou-

  bled in the ten years from the late 1980s, overtaking official Overseas Development Aid (ODA) by 1997. In 2001, the total amount remitted was over $70 billion, compared to just over $50 billion of ODA.

  Half of all remittances are to India, Mexico, the Philip-

  pines, Morocco, Egypt, and Turkey, but they can also be

  particularly important to smaller and island nations (for

  example they are, 37% of GDP in Tonga and 26% in

  Lesotho). The money sent improves the lives of people in

  receiving households, but also benefits the local economy

  via multiplier effects.

  Skilled returnees can help to establish new industries,

  for example, the high-tech sectors in Taiwan, India, and

  P1: OyK

  0521866790c07

  Printer: cupusbw

  CUFX043/Lomborg

  0 521 86679 0

  May 7, 2006

  17:16

  Population and Migration

  123

  Table 7.2. Migration: Economic impacts, 2001 data

  Countries

  World

  Low

  Middle

  High

  Population (m)

  6,133

  2,511

  2,667

  955

  Ave GDP($/year)

  5,140

  430

  1,850

  26,710

  Total GDP ($bn)

  31,500

  1,069

  4,922

  25,506

  Moving 100 million people from low to high, same

  per capita averages

  Population (m)

  2,411

  1,055

  Ave GDP($/year)

  5,566

  430

  26,710

  Total GDP ($bn)

  34,138

  1,037

  28,179

  GDP%

  8

  Moving 10 million people from low to high, same

  per capita averages

  Population (m)

  2,501

  965

  Ave GDP($/year)

  5,706

  430

  26,710

  Total GDP ($bn)

  31,760

  1,065

  25,773

  Change in ave/tot

 

‹ Prev