Billionaires and Stealth Politics

Home > Other > Billionaires and Stealth Politics > Page 18
Billionaires and Stealth Politics Page 18

by Benjamin I Page


  Finally, we expect that wealthy Republicans are more likely to engage

  in boundary control than wealthy Democrats. The boundary­ control strategy most naturally fits with support for Republican candidates, whose conservative political ideologies align well with billionaires’ self­ interested pursuit of small government on the national level.63 It is probably no coincidence that most of the industries with regulatory and market structures in which boundary control is attractive— including high­ polluting industries like energy and chemicals, and labor­ intensive and union­ averse manufacturing firms— have tended to be aligned with Republicans.64 Since

  it would be awkward at best for wealthy Democrats to engage in political

  strategies that require extensive public and private support for conservative Republicans, billionaires’ partisanship should matter.

  What the Evidence Says

  In order to test our expectations about boundary control, we expanded

  our data set on the one hundred wealthiest US billionaires to include measures of the regulatory structure and market structure faced by the main industry in which each billionaire was currently active. We coded each

  billionaire’s principal industry on four­ point scales indicating the intensity with which it was regulated (from light to very heavy), the sites of its regulation (from almost entirely national to almost entirely subnational), the extent of barriers to entry (from low to very high), and the net costs it imposed on the public in the areas in which it was located.65 Since the boundary­ control theory predicts that the strategy is adopted only when

  regulation is both heavy and subnational, we combined the intensity scale and the site of regulation scale to form an overall regulation index. We

  also summed the scores on each variable for each industry, in order to

  develop a total industry score for each industry.66

  114

  chapter five

  Sixteen of our one hundred billionaires were taking no active role in

  business during the period of study. Because the point of the boundary­

  control strategy is to obtain business­ specific financial benefits that are irrelevant to those not active in any business, the inactives were removed from this analysis. Of the remaining eighty­ four billionaires, forty­ three clearly were active only in a single industry, so we used the industry­ wide scores for that industry to code each of them. For the forty­ one billionaires who were active in two or more industries, we selected the industry that had the highest total score and coded each individual based on that

  industry.67 To ascertain billionaires’ party attachments, we used federal campaign contribution data to develop a measure of the party with which

  each billionaire was most aligned.68

  We measured billionaires’ use or nonuse of boundary control— our chief

  dependent variable— by examining national­ and subnational­ level contribution patterns. At the national level, boundary­ controlling contributors are (by definition) more likely to donate to outside groups— especially

  small­ government groups— or general party funds than to individual candidates. On the subnational level, they are more likely to make donations directly to candidates who are members of dominant state­ level parties

  than to outside groups or minority­ party candidates. At the state or local level, direct contributions to candidates or to individual candidates’ PACs are necessary as a means to “buy” their support for state­ level policy favors.

  We therefore coded billionaires as engaging in boundary­ control strategies if they met three criteria. First, they had to be active in a state with a dominant state­ level party, which we defined as any state that had had unified government (led by the same party) for six or more of the twelve

  years from 2000 to 2012.69 Second, at least two­ thirds of a billionaire’s national­ level contributions (in terms of total dollars) had to go to outside groups associated with small­ government causes or to Republican Party

  general funds. Finally, at least two­ thirds of their contributions within a state (again in terms of total dollars) had to go directly to candidates themselves (or to the PACs of those candidates) who are members of the

  dominant state­ level party.70

  One billionaire had to be dropped from the analysis because he was

  active in a state in which there was no online campaign finance database

  that allowed for searches by contributor, leaving eighty­ three billionaires to be analyzed. Of those eighty­ three billionaires, eight (nearly 10 percent of those studied, or 8 percent of our entire set of one hundred billionaires) met the criteria for engaging in boundary­ control strategies.71

  reshaping state and local politics

  115

  table 5.2 Firth Logistic Regression Model Predicting Use of Boundary Control 95% CI

  B (SE)

  p­ Value

  Lower

  Upper

  (Intercept)

  – 17.105 (5.876)

  <0.001

  – 33.210

  – 7.439

  Regulation Index

  2.632 (1.645)**

  0.038

  0.117

  7.593

  Barriers to Entry

  – 1.681 (2.018)

  0.369

  – 7.969

  2.829

  Concentrated Costs

  1.017 (1.677)

  0.494

  – 1.622

  10.266

  Party

  2.627 (1.632)**

  0.037

  0.128

  7.587

  ** p < .05.

  Note: Likelihood ratio test = 26.025 on 4 DF; p = .00003; n = 83. Wald test = 11.622 on 4 DF; p = .0204.

  All boundary controllers came from Republican­ dominated states.72

  Although both groups were highly active politically, boundary controllers contributed much more money to politics than non– boundary controllers— three times as much (an average annual sum of just over $1.5 million, compared with about $415,000). They also contributed more money to

  state politics than non– boundary controllers, particularly if one excludes ballot initiatives (to which a few individuals with intense preferences on social issues like same­ sex marriage have donated vast sums). Excluding ballot initiative contributions, boundary controllers on average made state­ level contributions of $109,425, nearly double the average annual

  amount contributed by others ($68,768). At the state level, in terms of

  total dollars, a much greater proportion of boundary controllers’ contributions (85 percent of them) than non– boundary controllers’ contributions (57 percent) went directly to candidates.73 On the national level, a much greater proportion of boundary controllers’ dollars (82 percent)

  than non– boundary controllers’ money (54 percent) went to outside

  groups or parties. The contrast was even greater (82 percent vs. 37 percent) in terms of the proportion of national level contributions that went to conservative groups or the Republican Party.

  Because of the limited number of billionaires studied, the rather few

  cases of boundary control, and the fact that the independent variables

  together caused quasi­ complete separation in a standard logistic regression model, we estimated the relationship between the variables in the data set using a Firth penalized likelihood logistic regression.74 The Firth approach helps with the problems of separation and rare outcomes.

  The main results of our analysis are presented in table 5.2. The model includes four independent variables: Regulation, Barriers to Entry, Net Public

  116

  chapter five

  table 5.3 Estimated Effects of Changes on Boundary- Control Independent Variables Average Treatment

  95% BCa CI

  Effect

  Standard Error

  Lower

  Upper

  Regulation Index />
  0.637

  0.195

  0.125

  0.851

  Party

  0.123

  0.044

  0.054

  0.233

  Note: “Average treatment effect” is the predicted change in probability of the outcome variable (i.e., boundary control) when moving from the minimum observed value on each independent variable to the maximum value.

  Standard errors were calculated using bootstrapping. Bias­ corrected and accelerated (BCa) confidence intervals (Efron 1987) are used to account for potential skewness in the bootstrap distribution.

  Costs, and Party. The Regulation and Party coefficients, which are very similar in terms of magnitude, are both statistically significant by the usual criteria. But the coefficients for Barriers to Entry and Net Public Costs are not statistically distinguishable from zero. So our analysis con firmed two of our expectations (hypotheses 1 and 4 in table 5.1) but did not provide support for two others (hypotheses 2 and 3). We earlier explained some possible reasons for those null findings.

  These results show a definite relationship between both regulatory

  structure and partisanship and the use of boundary control. These results are theoretically intelligible and statistically clear. Thus— while they do not prove a causal relationship— the quantitative findings suggest that boundary control is a distinctive strategy of Republican billionaires who do business in highly state­ regulated industries.

  In order to assess how big an impact regulatory structure and billionaires’ partisanship have on the likelihood of billionaires pursuing a boundary­ control strategy, we estimated average independent treatment

  effects for each: the predicted change in the probability of using boundary control when moving from the minimum to the maximum observed values on the regulation index variable75 or from Democrat to Republican

  in party affiliation. The results are presented in table 5.3.

  The estimated effect of an increase in state­ level regulation is a very substantial 0.637. That is, moving from the (observed) lower end of the regulatory structure variable to the higher end is estimated to increase the likelihood of the use of boundary control by fully 64 percent. The estimated effect of party (that is, of a billionaire shifting from Democrat to Republican) is a smaller but still meaningful 0.123, signifying a 12 percent increase in the likelihood of using boundary control. Thus a billionaire’s Republican Party affiliation is estimated to have a small but significant independent impact on the probability that the billionaire will pursue a boundary­ control strategy.

  reshaping state and local politics

  117

  But our estimates indicate that the regulatory structure of the billionaire’s main business (a large amount of state­ level regulation) very strongly tends to lead to efforts at boundary control.

  Case Studies to Improve Causal Inference

  As almost everyone knows, however, correlation is not causation. In order to make more confident causal inferences about which factors lead to the use of boundary­ control strategies, it is important to grapple with certain problems that quantitative analyses of observational data cannot

  by themselves adequately resolve. These problems include the possibility

  of omitted confounding variables (factors that, when left out, can distort or “confound” findings) and the possibility of measurement errors in independent variables of interest (which can lead to underestimates of the effects of those variables).

  Carefully designed case studies can enrich and deepen quantitative

  analyses by dealing with these problems, which are inherent in regression­

  type approaches to observational data.76 Case studies can also illuminate causal pathways, suggest temporal sequences, and contribute in other ways to the analysis of social and political processes.

  To advance our analysis of boundary­ control strategies, we selected for

  a closer look cases that were extreme (either extremely high or extremely low) on key independent variables. Such cases are ideally suited to identify omitted confounding variables, as well as to uncover any measurement error that may exist in independent variables of interest.77 It also turns out— not by accident— that such case selection often produces case

  studies that are interesting in themselves, illustrate the workings of the theory, and generate new ideas about causal processes.

  Measurement error in this context could consist of simple coding errors. Or it could reflect more profound problems in the way we measured variables of interest. (If, for example, some billionaires were deemed to be engaging in boundary control based on the way we operationalized

  that concept, but were found through closer examination to take actions

  that in some way indicated otherwise.) Measurement errors might also be

  revealed by the discovery of campaign contributions that escaped detection during the creation of the data set and alter our understanding of a billionaire’s political strategies.

  We identified extreme high and extreme low cases by summing individual billionaires’ scores on all the independent variables in the model (that is, all the factors we expected to lead to efforts at boundary control)

  118

  chapter five

  and locating who had the maximum and minimum total values in our data

  set. Harold Simmons was unique as the extreme high case, most strongly predicted to use boundary control. From among billionaires who tied as

  the extreme low case (least likely to use boundary control) we randomly

  selected George Soros.78

  We also selected a billionaire— Robert Rowling— who was typical (in terms of independent variables) of the eight who used boundary control.79

  Study of a typical case is useful for at least two reasons. First, it helps make an otherwise abstract theory more concrete and real. That is, it illustrates how a theory works. Second, and perhaps more importantly for us, studying one of our typical cases can help identify any politically important effects of using a boundary­ control strategy. Do boundary controllers actually receive direct benefits on the subnational level as a result of their contributions? Our quantitative model helps predict who does or does not try to use boundary control. But we also want to know whether that strategy actually pays off. Robert Rowling was randomly selected as a typical case from among the eight billionaires scored as utilizing boundary control.

  In each of the three case studies below, we first identify the billionaire’s financial interests, discuss them in terms of our independent variables

  (e.g., the regulatory and market structure of his businesses, and his party affiliation) and then detail his national and subnational­ level political activities, especially campaign contributions. We then assess whether or

  not our qualitative assessment aligns with the findings of the quantitative analysis, by searching for each of the potential sources of measurement

  error discussed above. Finally, for cases in which boundary control was

  used, we search for evidence on whether or not that strategy was successful in terms of accruing direct, subnational­ level financial benefits for the would­ be boundary controllers.

  harold simmons. The late Harold Simmons was selected as the extreme high case on the independent variables. (He scored higher on the sum of the four independent variables than any other billionaire studied.) So we strongly expected that he would engage in efforts at boundary control. And we coded him as having indeed done so.

  Simmons— born in Golden, Texas, in 1931, to two school­ teacher parents— spent his early childhood without indoor plumbing or electricity. He attended the University of Texas and was employed as a bank examiner

  along the way to becoming a wealthy industrialist active in metals, chemicals, waste management, and industrial manufacturing. Mainly through his

  reshaping state and local politics

  119

  privately held company, Cont
ran, Simmons had by 2013 accumulated a net

  worth of $10 billion.80 Simmons’s highest­ scoring company on the independent variables was his waste management firm, Waste Control Specialists.

  The waste management industry, which includes the disposal of highly toxic commercial waste, is very heavily regulated, mostly on the state and local levels. The waste management industry also has high barriers to entry and involves high localized public costs (pollution, unattractive sights and smells, and the risk of environmental and public health catastrophe if toxic waste is mishandled) with few compensating local public benefits.81

  Simmons was a major campaign contributor. His involvement in national politics— he once darkly proclaimed that Barack Obama was a

  “socialist”— has received a fair amount of attention from both academia

  and the mass media.82 Simmons’s political involvement on the state level, however, has been less noticed.

  On the national level, Simmons advocated for a small federal government and noninterference with the states. He supported conservative Republicans and attacked Democrats. Most notably, in 2004 Simmons contributed a substantial amount to the infamous “Swift Boat Veterans for Truth,”

  a group that then proceeded to run vicious attack ads about the military

  career of Democratic presidential candidate John Kerry, who had served

  honorably in Vietnam and received a purple heart. Simmons was also responsible for the Bill Ayers– Barack Obama attack ads of 2008, which attempted to link Obama to domestic terrorism.83 (Ayers, a rebel in his youth, was by 2008 a peaceable and mild­ mannered Chicago­ area scholar. Ayers

  and his acquaintances may have been puzzled by the idea of demonizing

  Obama for association with Ayers, but the ads made big waves nationally.) In the 2012 elections Simmons gave just shy of $27 million to conservative super PACs, most of which focused broadly on supporting conservatives in tight races rather than on aligning themselves with individual candidates.84 Simmons also contributed directly to some candidates or

  their individual PACs, but these donations paled in comparison to the

  donations he made to groups with a broader focus. In fact, he did not give more than $10,000 to any single candidate or any single candidate’s PAC.85

 

‹ Prev