Book Read Free

Paul Collier - Wars, Guns, and Votes

Page 8

by Democracy in Dangerous Places (pdf)


  homogenous villages were others that had been created as settle-

  ment schemes at various times, in which there were varying degrees

  of ethnic mix. She was able to show that controlling for other char-

  acteristics, the more ethnically mixed villages revealed a lower level

  of trust through the strategies people chose to play. Another result

  is that people are more willing to pay taxes to benefit people with

  whom they have an affinity than if they know that much of the ex-

  penditure will benefit people who are very different. When these

  results were reported in Europe, they produced a frisson of concern

  that immigration and the resulting change to multiethnic societies

  would erode the welfare states that characterize the continent.

  There is also evidence that the public good of scrutiny of gov-

  ernment breaks down. I have already recounted the anecdote about

  the Mercedes bought for the speaker of the Nigerian House, but

  there is more systematic evidence. A particularly convincing study

  compares the functioning of school boards in various parts of ru-

  ral Kenya. The school boards, composed of parents, can raise funds

  and manage the school: they thus have an important role to play in

  determining school quality. A clever study by Edward Miguel and

  Mary Kay Gugerty found that where the board was diverse, man-

  agement was worse: specifically, the members of the board were not

  prepared to criticize people from their own ethnic group who were

  failing to make contributions.

  Fortunately, there is a silver lining to ethnic diversity. The adverse

  effect of diversity on public provision is offset by an advantage that

  it confers in private economic activity. Why does diversity enhance

  private sector productivity? There is now pretty good experimental

  evidence that reveals what is going on, somewhat along the lines of

  Abigail’s work in Zimbabwe. Basically, diversity raises the productiv-

  ity of a team because it increases the range of skills, knowledge, and

  perspectives, and these help problem solving. Although diverse teams

  60

  WARS, GUNS, AND VOTES

  do not get along as well, they are better at achieving results. There is

  also some evidence that suggests that this scales up so as to affect the

  overall performance of an economy. I am not particularly proud of

  my own effort in this direction: I pushed to the limits of data avail-

  ability, and so the results are probably not that solid. But, for what it is worth, I constructed estimates, country by country, of the public and

  private capital stock and then investigated whether the productivity

  of these two types of capital was affected by the degree of ethnic diver-

  sity of the society. Each of these steps is precarious, but what came out

  was that ethnic diversity reduced the productivity of public capital,

  while increasing the productivity of private capital. While this may

  be spurious, it is at least consistent both with the micro-level evidence

  and with other macro-level results.

  One implication is that diverse societies should play to their ad-

  vantage and place as many activities as possible in the private sec-

  tor. This is clearly consistent with the contrast between America

  and Europe: the as yet more homogenous societies of Europe have

  a larger public sector. The societies of the bottom billion, with their

  high diversity, were particularly ill suited to the socialism that un-

  til recently has been overwhelmingly their predominant ideology.

  Their adoption of socialism was understandable: most of the first

  generation of political leaders had been educated in France and

  Britain in the 1950s. Not only had socialism been at its apogee, but

  to their great credit Europe’s socialists were the first politicians to

  support decolonization struggles. And beyond European socialism,

  imitating the Soviet model carried the sweetener of a ready access

  to armaments to address their security problems. One aspect of the

  so-called Structural Adjustment Programs of the 1980s was that

  African governments were encouraged or coerced into shifting ac-

  tivities from the public sector to the private sector. Though heavily

  criticized both for being coercive and for being ideologically driven,

  the direction of the shift was appropriate given the diverse composi-

  tion of Africa’s societies.

  Ethnic Politics

  61

  Since diversity has beneficial effects as well as adverse ones, it

  sounds as though with appropriate choices it might be a case of six of

  one and a half dozen of the other. The net effect might be negligible.

  However, you have already seen that an effect can be very different

  in high- and low-income societies. Recall that democracy reduces

  political violence in high-income societies but increases it in low-

  income societies. Could the effect of ethnic diversity be similar?

  Unfortunately for the societies of the bottom billion, it is. The

  beneficial effects of diversity only set in at higher levels of income:

  diversity is good news for America, and while Europe’s rising di-

  versity may well weaken its welfare state, it will be compensated by

  a more vibrant private economy. But it is bad news for Kenya and

  the other societies of the bottom billion. At low levels of income,

  diversity is a substantial net economic disadvantage, and it shows

  up in slower growth: a highly diverse low-income society on aver-

  age grows a full 2 percentage points less rapidly that a completely

  homogenous one. Why might diversity help high-income societies

  but hinder low-income societies? Perhaps it is because the key ad-

  vantages of diversity come from skills and knowledge. In an econ-

  omy with high levels of skills and knowledge, the larger the pool of

  diverse skills and knowledge, the better. But in economies where

  skills and knowledge are more rudimentary, there is less scope for

  diversity and less use for it.

  F u n da m e n ta l ly, t h e r e s u lt s s o fa r suggest that ethnic diversity makes social cooperation more difficult, and that at low

  income levels this effect is sufficiently strong to be a substantial im-

  pediment to prosperity. It is tempting to conclude from this that

  diverse societies cannot afford to rely upon cooperation to achieve

  the collective effort that is necessary for success in any economy.

  The alternative to achieving collective effort through cooperation

  is to achieve it through coercion. Someone is needed to direct the

  62

  WARS, GUNS, AND VOTES

  coercion: step forward the benign dictator. The recent evidence of

  China illustrates a more widespread phenomenon, that a society can

  make rapid economic progress if collective effort is guided by a suf-

  ficiently sensible and relatively benign autocratic leadership. Is this

  the answer for ethnically diverse low-income societies?

  The case for autocracy appears to be strengthened once we get

  back to the fundamental issue of security. You have already seen that

  in the bottom billion, democracy increases political violence in all its

  main forms. While dem
ocracy makes such societies more danger-

  ous, repression seems to work. We are back with the ugly fact that

  Saddam Hussein kept the peace in Iraq more effectively than Jalal

  Talabani. So better public goods—dictators make the trains run on

  time—and better security: the case for dictatorship looks disturb-

  ingly strong.

  While I do not want to discount the benefits from a sensible

  and benign autocrat, I think that for ethnically diverse societies, this

  solution to the problem of collective action is very dangerous. Ethnic

  diversity generates bad autocracies as well as bad democracies. In

  an ethnically diverse society dictators usually play the ethnic card,

  building their power base on their own ethnic group. As a result,

  their patronage base is almost inevitably narrow, not extending be-

  yond their ethnic group. The narrower the power base, the stronger

  is the incentive to retain power by raping the national economy and

  transferring the proceeds to their own ethnic group rather than by

  building the national economy and benefiting everyone. So, on this

  analysis, ethnically diverse societies would be supremely ill suited to

  dictatorship.

  Again, it is best to look at the evidence, but this particular ques-

  tion is far from straightforward. I started with a rough-and-ready

  attempt. What I found was that, judged by economic performance,

  ethnically diverse societies needed democracy more than those that

  were homogenous. If this result was correct, then far from needing

  a dictator, ethnically diverse societies were peculiarly ill suited to

  Ethnic Politics

  63

  them. While the result was sufficiently new to get published in a

  respectable academic journal, it was manifestly only a first step at an

  important question and quite possibly a misleading one. Recently

  Eliana La Ferrara and her distinguished coauthor Alberto Alesina,

  head of the economics department at Harvard, have revisited the

  issue and published a considerably more thorough analysis. I read

  their study with the mixed emotions of delight that the topic had

  engaged such a heavyweight team, admiration that they had pur-

  sued possibilities that I had missed, and, of course, trepidation that

  my own work might be revealed as a house of cards. In the academic

  world you are never more than one demolishing article away from

  humiliation.

  One important result that I had missed was that diversity was

  less damaging at higher levels of income. But potentially this spelled

  the death knell for my own result on democracy. Since democracy

  is more common at higher income, my result, which did not control

  for the level of income, may simply have been due to this correla-

  tion. They built up their analysis step by step, first replicating my

  result, then revealing their own, and finally combining the two pos-

  sibilities. Happily both for ethnically diverse democracies and for

  my own peace of mind, they found that both effects survived: ethnic

  diversity is less problematic at higher levels of income, and is differ-

  entially well suited to democracy. Even their analysis is only prelim-

  inary. As they acknowledge, there are various ways in which these

  results could be spurious. Nevertheless, the results caution against

  the leap from the problems of ethnic democratic politics to the infer-

  ence that what is needed is a dictator.

  Following their work I have tried to take the analysis a little

  further. Both my previous study and that of Alesina and La Ferrara

  took economic growth as the measure of performance. For some

  purposes this is not a bad measure. If there are indeed two offsetting

  effects of diversity, the key issue is whether the net effect is positive

  or negative. As a composite measure of performance, growth is as

  64

  WARS, GUNS, AND VOTES

  good as any. However, if, as seems likely, for the societies of the bot-

  tom billion the net effect is indeed negative, then we need to drill

  down. The adverse effects on public goods that are doing the dam-

  age must run through political or social choices. I therefore decided

  to switch from looking at the effects on growth to a more direct

  measure of these choices.

  The issue was evidently on the boundary between economics

  and politics, and I was fortunate to be able to team up with Robert

  Bates, like Alesina a professor at Harvard, and the undisputed doyen

  of political scientists working on Africa. For some years we have

  been part of a large team under the auspices of an African-directed

  research network. The team had been investigating the fraught

  topic of why Africa’s economies had largely stagnated during the

  forty years after 1960. Poor choices were by no means the only ex-

  planation for stagnation. For example, the fact that so many African

  countries were landlocked was a fundamental impediment to pros-

  perity. However, choices were clearly contributing factors, and the

  team decided to focus on those that were manifestly dysfunctional.

  We met up at Stanford one summer and went through the narra-

  tives of economic history, country by country. What emerged was a

  consensus on a few syndromes. One, for example, was the misman-

  agement of booms, gearing them up by borrowing and then squan-

  dering the proceeds. We found that where countries stayed clear

  of these syndromes they always avoided economic collapse, even if

  they did not grow rapidly.

  Bates and I decided to use these killer syndromes as our mea-

  sure of performance. Did ethnic diversity make a country more

  prone to these highly dysfunctional choices? We found that the ru-

  inous combination was high diversity together with severe political

  repression. This was the cocktail that had produced Africa’s dys-

  functional social choices. Indeed, it was only through this lethal in-

  teraction that diversity and dictatorship made a society more prone

  to the syndromes. It was not dictatorship in itself, or diversity in it-

  Ethnic Politics

  65

  self, but only their combination. This result, which is entirely based

  on variation among African societies, is clearly consistent with the

  globally based results: ethnically diverse low-income societies are

  particularly ill suited to autocracy.

  Finally I turn to what is to my mind the most insightful study:

  an as yet unpublished paper by Tim Besley and his student Masayuki

  Kudamatsu, provocatively entitled “Making Autocracy Work.”

  They show that performance in autocracies is far more dispersed

  than that in democracies: autocracies can be extremely successful

  but also utterly ruinous. Their question is what drives the differ-

  ence: why were none of the successful autocracies in Africa? They

  build their answer around the notion of a selectariat. A selectariat

  is what a dictatorship has instead of an electorate: it is the limited

  group of people on whom power rests. These are the people who

  could therefore potentially oust the dictator if he performs badly.

  Besley and Kudamatsu d
iscovered that the difference between suc-

  cessful and ruinous dictatorships is whether the selectariat is willing

  to use this power. Where selectariats routinely ditch incompetent

  dictators, the autocracy performs well.

  This result is important, but it raises a further question: what

  determines whether the selectariat is willing to ditch a failing dicta-

  tor? They come up with a simple answer. The selectariat will only

  dump the dictator if it is confident of retaining power, replacing him

  with one of their own. Here, I think, lies the explanation for why

  autocracy goes wrong in societies stratified by strong ethnic identi-

  ties: in such societies political change is risky. The current selectariat

  will be drawn from the ethnic group of the dictator, but if it ousts

  him, it may trigger a chain of events in which power passes to a rival

  ethnic group and thus to a new selectariat. When I discuss coups you

  will find evidence consistent with this: in Africa ethnic polarization

  strongly increases the risk of a coup. An ethnic selectariat would be

  right to be fearful of disturbing the status quo. Consistent with this

  argument, Besley and Kudamatsu find that ethnic diversity reduces

  66

  WARS, GUNS, AND VOTES

  the chances that an autocracy will work. But they also find evidence

  that ethnic diversity is far from being the whole story: its effects can

  be overridden. A strong ideology such as Marxism makes autocracy

  more likely to succeed even in the context of ethnic diversity. If the

  selectariat consists of the Communist Party, whoever heads the dic-

  tatorship, the party is going to remain in power. The societies of the

  bottom billion do not need another dose of Marxism. But they do

  need something that gives a sense of common identity.

  So, while neither economic theory nor statistical analysis has

  yet been able decisively to nail the issue, as far as we can tell it looks

  as though the tough autocrat who rules by fear is precisely what the

  diverse societies of the bottom billion most need to avoid. Although

  they are able to keep the lid on political violence other than their

  own, measured on a wider array of criteria, they are a disaster. Di-

  versity may make democratic politics deteriorate, but it is likely to

  make dictatorship lethal.

  S o h ow c a n e t h n i c d i v e r s i t y be overcome? A sense of national identity does not grow out of the soil: it is constructed by

 

‹ Prev