Book Read Free

The Economics of Artificial Intelligence

Page 77

by Ajay Agrawal


  71 (2): 405– 09.

  Romanosky, Sasha. 2016. “Examining the Costs and Causes of Cyber Incidents.”

  Journal of Cybersecurity 2 (2): 121– 35.

  Romanosky, Sasha, Alessandro Acquisti, and Rahul Telang. 2011. “Do Data Breach

  Disclosure Laws Reduce Identity Theft?” Journal of Policy Analysis and Manage-

  ment 30 (2): 256– 86.

  Romanosky, Sasha, David Hoff man, and Alessandro Acquisti. 2014. “Empirical

  Analysis of Data Breach Litigation.” Journal of Empirical Legal Studies 11 (1): 74– 104.

  Silver, David, Julian Schrittwieser, Karen Simonyan, Ioannis Antonoglou, Aja

  Huang, Arthur Guez, Thomas Hubert, Lucas Baker, Matthew Lai, Adrian

  Bolton, Yutian Chen, Timothy Lillicrap, Fan Hui, Laurent Sifre, George van den

  Driessche, Thore Graepel, and Demis Hassabis. 2017. “Mastering the Game of

  Go without Human Knowledge.” Nature 550:354– 59.

  462 Ginger Zhe Jin

  Solove, Daniel. 2013. Nothing to Hide: The False Tradeoff between Privacy and Security. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

  Stigler, George J. 1980. “An Introduction to Privacy in Economics and Politics.”

  Journal of Legal Studies 9 (4): 623– 44.

  Stutzman, Fred, Ralph Gross, and Alessandro Acquisti. 2012. “Silent Listeners:

  The Evolution of Privacy and Disclosure on Facebook.” Journal of Privacy and

  Confi dentiality 4 (2): 7– 41.

  Swire, Peter P., and Robert E. Litan. 1998. None of Your Business: World Data

  Flows, Electronic Commerce, and the European Privacy Directive. Washington,

  DC: Brookings Institution Press.

  Tang, Jun, Aleksandra Korolova, Xiaolong Bai, Xueqiang Wang, and Xiaofeng

  Wang. 2017. “Privacy Loss in Apple’s Implementation of Diff erential Privacy on

  MacOS 10.12.” https:// arxiv .org/ pdf/ 1709.02753 .pdf.

  Telang, Rahul, and Sriram Somanchi. 2017. “Security, Fraudulent Transactions and

  Customer Loyalty: A Field Study.” Working paper, Carnegie Mellon University.

  Telang, Rahul, and Sunil Wattal. 2007. “An Empirical Analysis of the Impact of

  Software Vulnerability Announcements on Firm Stock Price.” IEEE Transactions

  on Software Engineering 33 (8): 544– 57.

  Thales. 2017a. 2017 Thales Data Threat Report: Trends in Encryption and Data Secu-

  rity (Financial Services Edition). https:// dtr- fi n.thalesesecurity .com/.

  Thales. 2017b. 2017 Thales Data Threat Report: Trends in Encryption and Data Secu-

  rity (Global Edition). https:// dtr.thalesesecurity .com/.

  Thomas, Kurt, Frank Li, Ali Zand, Jacob Barrett, Juri Ranieri, Luca Invernizzi,

  Yarik Markov, Oxana Comanescu, Vijay Eranti, Angelika Moscicki, Daniel

  Margolis, Vern Paxson, and Elie Bursztein. 2017. “Data Breaches, Phishing, or

  Malware? Understanding the Risks of Stolen Credentials.” Proceedings of the

  2017 ACM SIGSAC Conference on Computer and Communications Security,

  1421– 34. https:// acmccs.github.io/ papers/ p1421-thomasAembCC .pdf.

  Varian, Hal R. 1997. “Economics Aspects of Personal Privacy.” In Privacy and Self-

  Regulation in the Information Age. Washington, DC: US Department of Com-

  merce, National Telecommunications and Information Administration.

  Vines, Paul, Franziska Roesner, and Tadayoshi Kohno. 2017. “Exploring ADINT:

  Using Ad Targeting for Surveillance on a Budget—or—How Alice Can Buy Ads

  to Track Bob.” The 16th ACM Workshop on Privacy in the Electronic Society

  (WPES 2017).

  Warren, Samuel, and Louis Brandeis. 1890. “The Right to Privacy.” Harvard Law

  Review 4:191.

  19

  Artifi cial Intelligence and

  International Trade

  Avi Goldfarb and Daniel Trefl er

  The last 200 years have produced a remarkable list of major innovations, not

  the least of which is artifi cial intelligence (AI). Like other major innovations,

  AI will likely raise average incomes and improve well- being, but it may also

  disrupt labor markets, raise inequality, and drive noninclusive growth. Yet,

  even to the extent that progress has been made in understanding the impact

  of AI, we remain largely uninformed about its international dimensions.

  This is to our great loss. A number of countries are currently negotiating

  international agreements that will constrain the ability of sovereign gov-

  ernments to regulate AI, such as the North American Trade Agreement

  (NAFTA) and the Trans- Pacifi c Partnership (TPP)- 11. Likewise, govern-

  ments around the world are freely spending public funds on new AI clusters

  designed to shift international comparative advantage toward their favored

  regions, including the Vector Institute in Toronto and the Tsinghua- Baidu

  deep- learning lab around Beijing. The international dimensions of AI inno-

  vations and policies have not always been well thought out. This work begins

  the conversation.

  China has become the focal point for much of the international discus-

  sion. The US narrative has it that Chinese protection has reduced the ability

  Avi Goldfarb holds the Rotman Chair in Artifi cial Intelligence and Healthcare and is professor of marketing at the Rotman School of Management, University of Toronto, and a research associate of the National Bureau of Economic Research. Daniel Trefl er holds the J. Douglas and Ruth Grant Canada Research Chair in Competitiveness and Prosperity at the University of Toronto and is a research associate of the National Bureau of Economic Research.

  The authors thank Dave Donaldson and Hal Varian for their thoughtful feedback. Trefl er acknowledges the support of the “Institutions, Organizations and Growth” Program of the Canadian Institute for Advanced Research (CIFAR). For acknowledgments, sources of

  research support, and disclosure of the authors’ material fi nancial relationships, if any, please see http:// www .nber .org/ chapters/ c14012.ack.

  463

  464 Avi Goldfarb and Daniel Trefl er

  of dynamic US fi rms such as Google and Amazon to penetrate Chinese mar-

  kets. This protection has allowed China to develop signifi cant commercial

  AI capabilities, as evidenced by companies such as Baidu (a search engine

  like Google), Alibaba (an e-commerce web portal like Amazon), and Ten-

  cent (the developer of WeChat, which can be seen as combining the func-

  tions of Skype, Facebook, and Apple Pay). While no Chinese AI- intensive

  company has household recognition outside of China, everyone agrees that

  this will not last. Further, a host of behind- the- border regulatory asymme-

  tries will help Chinese fi rms to penetrate Canadian and US markets.

  Even the Pentagon is worried. Chinese guided- missile systems are suffi

  -

  ciently sophisticated that they may disrupt how we think of modern warfare;

  large and expensive military assets such as aircraft carriers are becoming

  overly vulnerable to smart weapons.1 This may do more than transform the

  massive defense industry; these AI developments may radically shift the

  global balance of power.

  As international economists, we are used to hype and are typically dis-

  missive of it. Despite AI’s short life—Agrawal, Gans, and Goldfarb (2018)

  date its commercial birth to 2012—AI’s rapid insinuation into our daily

  economic and social activities forces us to evaluate the international impli-

  cations of AI and propose best- policy responses. Current policy responses


  often rest on a US narrative of a zero- sum game in which either the United

  States or China will win.2 Is this the right premise for examining AI impacts

  and for developing AI policies? Further, calls for immediate action by

  prominent experts such as Bill Gates, Stephen Hawking, and Elon Musk

  will likely encourage governments to loosen their pocketbooks, but will

  government subsidies be eff ective in promoting broad- based prosperity or

  will subsidies become yet another form of ineff ective corporate welfare?

  What specifi c policies are likely to tip the balance away from ineff ective

  corporate handouts?

  Using comparative advantage theory, trade economists have thought

  long and hard about the right mix of policies for successfully promoting

  industry. Many of our theories imply a laissez- faire free- trade approach.

  However, since the early 1980s our theories have shown that certain types of

  government interventions may be successful, for example, Krugman (1980),

  Grossman and Helpman (1991), and the more informal theories of Porter

  (1990). These theories emphasize the role of scale and the role of knowledge

  creation and diff usion. Unfortunately, the precise policy prescriptions pro-

  duced by these theories are very sensitive to the form of scale and the form

  1. New York Times, Feb. 3, 2017. See also Preparing for the Future of Artifi cial Intelligence, Offi

  ce of the President, Oct., 2016.

  2. For example, https:// www .economist .com/ news/ business/ 21725018-its- deep- pool- data

  - may- let- it- lead- artifi cial- intelligence- china- may- match- or- beat- america and http:// www

  .reuters .com/ article/ us- usa- china- artificialintelligence/ u- s- weighs- restricting- chinese

  - investment- in-artifi cial- intelligence- idUSKBN1942OX?il=0.

  Artifi cial Intelligence and International Trade 465

  of knowledge creation/ diff usion. And competition can play an important

  role too, for example, in Aghion et al. (2001, 2005) and Lim, Trefl er and

  Yu (2017).

  We therefore start in section 19.2 by identifying the key features of AI

  technology in regard to scale and knowledge. To date there are no mod-

  els that feature the particular scale and knowledge characteristics that are

  empirically relevant for AI. In section 19.3 we use these features (a) to off er

  some suggestions for what an appropriate model might look like, and (b) to

  draw implications for policy. This leads to high- level thinking about policy.

  For example, it provides a foundation for assessing recent proposals put

  forward by AI researcher Geoff Hinton and others on the potential benefi t

  of public investments in AI.3 However, these models are not suffi

  ciently

  fi ne- grained to directly capture existing regulatory issues that “go behind the

  border” such as privacy policy, data localization, technology standards, and

  industrial regulation. In section 19.4 we therefore review the many behind-

  the- border policies that already impact AI and discuss their implications for

  comparative advantage and the design of trade agreements. We begin with

  a factual overview of the international dimensions of AI.

  19.1 From Hype to Policy

  Statistics about where AI is being done internationally and how it is dif-

  fusing can be tracked in a number of ways, for example, the number of

  basic research articles, patents and patent citations produced in a region;

  the number of start-ups established in a region; or the market capitaliza-

  tion of publicly traded AI- based companies in a region. We look at two of

  these indicators: basic research and market capitalization. For the former,

  we collected time- series data on the institutional affi

  liation of all authors of

  papers presented at a major AI research conference, namely, the Association

  for the Advancement of Artifi cial Intelligence (AAAI) Conference on Arti-

  fi cial Intelligence. In table 19.1, we compare the 2012 and 2017 conferences.

  In 2012, 41 percent of authors were at US institutions, but by 2017 this was

  down to 34 percent. The two other largest declines were recorded by Canada

  and Israel. While these countries all increased their absolute number of par-

  ticipants, in relative terms they all lost ground to China, which leapt from

  10 percent in 2012 to 23 percent in 2017.

  We have not examined patent numbers, but suggestive work by Fujii and

  Managi (2017) points to weaker international diff usion of AI: US tech-

  nology giants such as IBM and Microsoft remain far and away the world’s

  dominant patent applicants.

  Another indication of the economic future of AI comes from the largest

  3. “Artifi cial Intelligence is the Future, and Canada Can Seize It” by Jordan Jacobs, Tomi Poutanen, Richard Zemel, Geoff rey Hinton, and Ed Clark. Globe and Mail, Jan. 7, 2017.

  466 Avi Goldfarb and Daniel Trefl er

  Table 19.1

  Participants at a major AI conference

  Country

  2012 (%)

  2017 (%)

  Change (%)

  United States

  41

  34

  – 6

  China

  10

  23

  13

  United Kingdom

  5

  5

  0

  Singapore

  2

  4

  2

  Japan

  3

  4

  1

  Australia

  6

  3

  – 2

  Canada

  5

  3

  – 3

  India

  1

  2

  1

  Hong Kong

  3

  2

  – 1

  Germany

  4

  2

  – 1

  France

  4

  2

  – 2

  Israel

  4

  2

  – 3

  Italy

  2

  2

  – 1

  Other

  10

  10

  0

  Notes: Participation rates at the Association for the Advancement of Artifi cial Intelligence (AAAI) Conference on Artifi cial Intelligence. For example, of the papers presented at the 2017 conference, 34 percent of authors had a US affi

  liation.

  public companies in the world by market capitalization. Table 19.2 lists the

  twelve largest companies worldwide. What is striking about the table is the

  number of companies that might subjectively be described as “AI intensive.”

  Seven of the twelve companies are heavily engaged in AI (such as Alphabet/

  Google), three are in fi nance (where the use of AI is growing rapidly), and

  one has a substantial pharmaceutical presence (where AI is likely to soon

  be reducing development costs). What makes table 19.2 relevant for inter-

  national trade is the fact that two of the largest companies worldwide are

  now Chinese AI- intensive fi rms (Tencent and Alibaba). It is truly remark-

  able that two high- tech companies based out of China—private companies,

  not state- owned enterprises—are among the largest companies in the world.

  While we had to move beyond the round number of ten to make this point, it

&
nbsp; is striking nonetheless. It points to the major global shake-up that is coming.

  Some would conclude from tables 19.1 and 19.2 that almost all of the

  world’s largest companies will soon be competing directly against Chinese

  companies when—not if—these Chinese companies go global. In 2000,

  Robin Li signaled his agreement by moving to China to establish Baidu.

  The fl ood of US- trained talent returning to China has continued. This year,

  former Microsoft executive Qi Lu joined Baidu as chief operating offi

  cer

  (COO). In describing China, Lu writes, “We have an opportunity to lead

  in the future of AI.”4 Not everyone agrees. Some have argued that China’s

  AI- intensive companies will not be globally competitive until they compete

  head-on in China with global leaders such as Google. This fl ies in the face of

  4. The Economist, July 15, 2017.

  Artifi cial Intelligence and International Trade 467

  Table 19.2

  World’s largest public companies and AI exposure

  Company

  Market value ($)

  AI exposure

  1. Apple

  754

  High

  2. Alphabet

  579

  High

  3. Microsoft

  509

  High

  4. Amazon

  423

  High

  5. Berkshire Hathaway

  411

  Rising

  6. Facebook

  411

  High

  7. ExxonMobil

  340

  Low

  8. Johnson & Johnson

  338

  Rising

  9. JPMorgan Chase

  314

  Rising

  10. Wells Fargo

  279

  Rising

  11. Tencent Holdings

  272

  High

  12. Alibaba

  269

  High

  Notes: Market capitalization of the largest public companies as of March 31, 2017, from PWC

  (2017). “AI exposure” is our subjective assessment of the role of AI in company performance.

  a long history of Chinese export successes in other fi elds. Indeed, Sutton and

  Trefl er (2016) describe both theoretically and empirically how developing

  countries such as China initially enter new markets at a low level of quality,

  but over time develop the capabilities to deliver high- quality, internationally

 

‹ Prev