BLAIR’S BRITAIN, 1997–2007

Home > Young Adult > BLAIR’S BRITAIN, 1997–2007 > Page 69
BLAIR’S BRITAIN, 1997–2007 Page 69

by ANTHONY SELDON (edt)


  life expectancy and the average; and the second to reduce the gap in infant

  mortality between manual groups and the population as a whole by at least

  10% by 2010. Policies, however, were thinner on the ground – to the extent

  that a 2004 Treasury review concluded that ‘after many years of reviews and

  government policy documents, with little change on the ground, the key

  challenge now is delivery and implementation, not further discussion’.43

  The main policy emphasis was on overall levels of health and increased

  spending on health care. Health spending rose as a share of GDP from

  5.7% in 1998 to 9.4% in 2006 – and, as for education, funding formulae

  were reformed to channel more resources to disadvantaged areas. In addition, Health Action Zones were set up, aimed at developing local programmes to tackle health inequalities in collaboration with social services,

  voluntary and business organisations and local communities. However,

  despite strong evidence of the importance of childhood health as a driver

  of health in adulthood, there was no overarching health strategy for children. The policy for very early childhood relied mainly on Sure Start, with

  Public Service Agreements to reduce low birth weight, emergency hospital

  admissions, smoking in pregnancy and re-registrations with the child

  protection register in Sure Start areas (covering just one-third of poor

  children). There were also small initiatives such as the National School

  Fruit Scheme, which provides every schoolchild aged four to six with a

  daily free piece of fruit; and increases in funding to improve the quality of

  school lunches in the aftermath of chef Jamie Oliver’s high-profile campaign on the issue. At the tail end of the Blair premiership, the 2007

  Budget announced the extension of child benefit to women from week

  twenty-nine of their pregnancy – a welcome recognition that a child’s

  health is affected by maternal nutrition well before birth.

  In practice, the share of babies born at low birth weight rose slightly

  across social classes between 1997 and 2004.44 The social class differential

  42 Department of Health (DoH), Independent Inquiry into Inequalities in Health Report

  (London: TSO, 1998); DoH, Saving Lives: Our Healthier Nation (London: TSO, 1999);

  DoH, Tackling Health Inequalities: A Programme for Action (London: DoH, 2003). For

  further discussion see Franco Sassi, ‘Tackling Health Inequalities’, in Hills and Stewart, A

  More Equal Society?

  43 Derek Wanless, Securing Good Health for the Whole Population (London: HM Treasury,

  2004), cited in Sassi, ‘Tackling Health Inequalities’.

  44 A rising share of babies born with low birth weight can reflect technological advances

  which enable more premature babies to be kept alive at birth, so should not in itself be

  

   

  rose between 1997 and 1999 and fell back thereafter, leaving no change

  overall: in 2004, as in 1997, children from social classes 5–8 were

  one quarter more likely to be born weighing less than 2.5 kilograms than

  children from classes 1–4. The class differential in infant mortality

  increased slightly between 1997 and 2005, though it peaked in 2003: in

  this case progress has been made for all groups, but gains have been a little

  greater for higher social classes. The most recent data on spatial

  differences in life expectancy are also discouraging: the gap between

  England as a whole and the poorest fifth of local authorities widened by

  2% for males and 8% for females between 1995–7 and 2003–5.45 For

  adults it is arguably much too early to judge the impact of any recent

  changes, given both lags in data and the speed with which policy might be

  expected to affect health outcomes. But the lack of progress in reducing

  health inequality for young children is more worrying – both because the

  challenge of reducing later inequality after an unequal start is far greater,

  and because young children’s health ought to be quick to respond to

  effective policy.

  Income inequality

  Reducing the level of overall income inequality was explicitly not a goal

  for the Blair government. Blair repeatedly emphasised that his concern

  was with the bottom half of the income distribution rather than the top

  half, and with ‘equality of opportunity’ not ‘equality of outcome’. As he

  put it in a Fabian Society pamphlet in 2002, ‘We favour true equality:

  equal worth and equal opportunity, not an equality of outcome focused

  on incomes alone.’46 Or, more colourfully, on Newsnight in 2001: ‘It’s not

  a burning ambition of mine to make sure that David Beckham earns less

  money.’47

  In practice, figure 19.4 shows that incomes rose marginally faster for

  the poorer groups than for the richer groups during the Blair era. This

  Footnote 44 ( cont. )

  seen as a negative trend: the social class differential is more informative. Data for low birth

  weight and infant mortality is from the Office for National Statistics (Childhood, Infant

  and Perinatal Mortality Statistics for England and Wales, Series DH3).

  45 DoH, Tackling Health Inequalities: 2003–05 Data Update for the National 2010 PSA Target

  (London: DoH, 2006).

  46 Tony Blair, The Courage of our Convictions: Why Reform of the Public Services Is the Route to

  Social Justice, Fabian Ideas 603 (London: Fabian Society, 2002), p. 2.

  47 Cited in Tom Sefton and Holly Sutherland, ‘Inequality and Poverty under New Labour’, in

  Hills and Stewart, A More Equal Society?

     

  

  Blair:1996/7–2005/6

  4

  3

  2

  1

  0

  Poorest

  2

  3

  4

  Richest

  Major:1990–1996/7

  4

  3

  2

  1

  0

  Poorest

  2

  3

  4

  Richest

  Thatcher:1979–1990

  4

  3

  2

  1

  0

  Poorest

  2

  3

  4

  Richest

  Figure 19.4. Real income growth by quintile group under Tony Blair, John Major and

  Margaret Thatcher (% per year).

  Source: Brewer et al., Poverty and Inequality in the UK: 2007, table 4.

  Notes: Averages in each quintile group correspond to the midpoints, i.e. the tenth,

  thirtieth, fiftieth, seventieth and ninetieth percentile points of the income

  distribution. Incomes have been measured before the deduction of housing costs.

  

   

  0.40

  0.35

  0.30

  0.25

  Thatcher

  Major

  Blair

  0.20

  1979

  1981

  1983

  1985

  1987

  1989

  1991 1993/941995/961997/981999/002001/022003/042005/06

  Figure 19.5. The Gini coefficient 1979–2004/5

  Source: based on figure 8 in Brewer et al., Poverty an
d Inequality in the UK: 2007; data

  from Institute for Fiscal Studies website (www.ifs.org.uk).

  Note: The Gini coefficient has been calculated using incomes before the deduction of

  housing costs.

  contrasts sharply to the situation under Margaret Thatcher, shown at the

  bottom of the figure. While the average annual rate of growth was similar

  (mean growth of 2.8% under Thatcher compared to 2.3% under Blair),

  during the Thatcher years growth was skewed heavily towards the richest.

  Under John Major the lower income groups did best in relative terms, but

  growth was very low for everyone.

  The pattern of growth under Blair meant, as we have seen, sharp

  improvements in the real living standards of the poorest, especially for

  children and pensioners, and more modest declines in relative poverty

  for these groups. But overall income inequality remained fairly static.

  Figure 19.5 shows the change in one summary measure of income

  inequality, the Gini coefficient, which takes a value between zero (complete equality) and 1 (if one person receives all the income and the others

  nothing). The Gini rose slightly during Blair’s first term to reach a record

  level of 0.35 in 2000/1. It fell slightly in the second term, but by 2005/6 it

  was back up to the 0.35 high.

  Why has inequality not fallen, despite the many measures taken – successfully – to raise the incomes of the poorest? For one thing, this was

     

  

  largely a time of strong economic growth, and in such periods inequality

  tends to rise. Certainly tax-benefit changes have had difficulty keeping up

  with rapid increases in median incomes, which is why relative poverty

  indicators have fallen much more slowly than indicators using a fixed

  income poverty line. But more importantly for the Gini measure, income

  at the very top of the income distribution – in particular among the

  richest 1% or even 0.5% of individuals – increased far more quickly than

  average. The income shares of both the top 1% and the top 0.5%, which

  had been falling throughout the century for as far as records go back, have

  been on the increase since the early 1980s, with a particularly sharp rise

  since 1998.48 This has not affected poverty indicators (measured against

  the median) but has influenced inequality indicators which reflect the full

  distribution, such as the Gini. The major contributor to income inequality is earnings inequality, and this continued to widen after 1997, particularly in the top half of the distribution: the ratio between the earnings of

  those at the ninetieth percentile and those at the median reached an alltime high of 2.0 in 2003, although it dropped very slightly thereafter.49

  Growing income inequality also contributed to rapidly widening disparities in wealth. Excluding housing assets, the share of wealth owned by the

  richest 10% of the population rose from 57% to 63% in the two decades

  to 1996, and then from 63% to 71% in the following seven years under

  Labour; the share belonging to the top 1% also increased sharply.50

  Micro-simulation by Tom Sefton and Holly Sutherland indicates that

  the Gini coefficient in 2004/5 was significantly lower than it would have

  been if the 1997 tax-benefit system had been left in place and only adjusted

  for inflation: the reduction in the Gini compared to that scenario is about

  one-third of the size of the rise of the previous twenty years.51 The Gini is

  also lower than it would have been under a more generous scenario, in

  which the 1997 system was adjusted for average income growth, though the

  impact in this case is reduced by about half. In sum, while tax-benefit

  changes under Labour were quite strongly redistributive, they worked

  against the tide of pre-tax and benefit growth in earnings, and were only

  sufficient to prevent further increases in inequality, not to reduce it.

  48 Anthony B. Atkinson, Top Incomes in the United Kingdom over the Twentieth Century,

  University of Oxford Discussion Papers in Economic and Social History 43 (Oxford:

  University of Oxford, 2002).

  49 Sefton and Sutherland, ‘Inequality and Poverty under New Labour’.

  50 ONS statistics at www.statistics.gov.uk/cci/nugget.asp?idϭ2. Housing assets are more

  evenly distributed than other wealth, but the time trends are very similar.

  51 Sefton and Sutherland, ‘Inequality and Poverty under New Labour’.

  

   

  Of course, Labour could have taken measures to try to limit the growth

  of earnings inequality. The government could have attempted negotiation to address rising rates of city pay and bonuses, which have grown on

  Blair’s watch to levels unacceptable to many. Or it could have moved

  beyond the quiet redistribution which has funded tax credits for the lowpaid through hidden measures such as the non-indexation of tax rate

  bands (dubbed ‘redistribution by stealth’) and introduced a higher rate of

  income taxation. This was ruled out in each of Blair’s three parliaments

  by manifesto commitments not to raise either the basic or the top rate of

  income taxation – a pledge first made in the nervousness before the 1997

  election and repeated at each subsequent election. There would have been

  clear pragmatic gains to be made from a higher rate, raising resources to

  fund further reductions in child poverty, for example. But a real attempt

  to tackle incomes at the top and bring income inequality down would

  also have made an enormous difference in itself to the shape of British

  society in 2007. Blair’s position that the incomes of the rich are of no relevance to the rest of the country other than as a source of envy is difficult

  to defend. One manifestation of their importance is the annual contribution of city bonuses to record levels of house price inflation since 1997,

  which have fast created a new wealth divide between those who already

  own homes or stand to gain from a housing inheritance and those who do

  not. Just in themselves, such wildly differing levels of remuneration, far

  beyond anything which may be justifiable on meritocratic grounds, are

  unfair and are seen as unfair, creating a sense of injustice which affects

  individual morale and national solidarity.

  Blair’s legacy: a more equal society?

  It is undoubtedly the case that Blair’s Labour government took the levels

  of poverty and social injustice plaguing Britain in the 1990s extremely

  seriously – far more seriously than many would have expected when

  Labour came to power on a fairly modest manifesto in 1997. The evidence sketched out in this chapter points to intervention across a very

  wide range of areas – addressing child and pensioner poverty, worklessness and educational disadvantage, improving the opportunities available to very young children and their parents, and tackling the multiple

  problems facing people living in deprived neighbourhoods. In many

  cases policy has seen considerable success; in other areas less so. It is

  always possible to argue that more could and should have been done, but

  a look back to figure 19.1 reminds us of the scale of the task that Labour

     

  

  faced. O
verall Britain is a fairer and more equal society in 2007 than it was

  in 1997, and it is almost certainly far more equal than it would have been

  after another ten years of Conservative government.

  What was Blair’s personal contribution to these changes? Most obviously, his unexpected pledge to eradicate child poverty had an enormous

  impact. Without such a pledge it is unlikely that benefit changes favouring children would have developed as far or as fast, or been given such

  priority – although a committed Gordon Brown in the Treasury was

  arguably more important in ensuring delivery. More generally, the

  ‘opportunity for all’ agenda, with its emphasis on the importance of tackling disparities in life chances from birth onwards, appears to bear Blair’s

  stamp.

  At the same time, however, it is difficult not to look back at the Blair

  decade with a sense that the opportunity for even greater change was

  missed. Early on, many who wanted to see Labour tackle overall inequality as well as poverty believed that Blair was holding back for fear of

  upsetting the electorate, but as the decade progressed it became more

  than clear that this was not a Prime Minister unwilling to take on an

  unpopular policy and stick by it in the face of widespread opposition. It is

  apparent now that there were limits to Blair’s commitment to social

  justice, and his main priorities lay elsewhere. If his mission had only been

  a different one – if it had led him to take on inequality as his enemy – he

  might have left behind an entirely different landscape.

  20

  Culture and attitudes

   

  After a decade in power most politicians’ popularity is in decline. Tony

  Blair’s was no exception. However, focusing only on the popular and

  media mood towards the end of his term in office risks missing the wood

  for the trees. We should look back at the man and his standing with the

  British public with respect – at least in the period 1994–2002. Ratings of

  Blair’s performance in Opposition were virtually unprecedented in

  polling history. Compare his performance as Leader of the Opposition

  with the four Conservatives, including David Cameron, who followed

  him in this role (Figure 20.1).

  From the time he assumed leadership of the Labour Party, Blair’s

  personal rating was one of the highest recorded. And after he became

  Prime Minister, he was the most popular Prime Minister recorded in the

 

‹ Prev