Book Read Free

BLAIR’S BRITAIN, 1997–2007

Page 79

by ANTHONY SELDON (edt)


  usually means ‘whatever the governing party’s whips can persuade their

  19 See McLean and McMillan, State of the Union, tables 8.3 and 8.11; John Curtice, ‘Restoring

  Confidence and Legitimacy? Devolution and Public Opinion’, in Trench, Has Devolution

  Made a Difference? , figure 9.8.

  10 George Tsebelis, Veto Players: How Political Institutions Work (Princeton, NJ: Princeton

  University Press, 2002), pp. 2, 8–9.

  

   

  2.00

  1.50

  Labour

  Lib Dem

  1.00

  SNP

  Ratio

  Conservative

  0.50

  Other

  0

  HC1997

  SP1999

  HC2001

  SP2003

  HC2005

  SP2007

  Year

  Figure 22.1. Seat/vote ratios in Scotland

  2.00

  1.80

  1.60

  1.40

  1.20

  Labour

  Ratio

  Lib Dem

  1.00

  Plaid Cymru

  0.80

  Conservative

  Other

  0.60

  0.40

  0.20

  0.00

  HC1997

  NAW1999

  HC2001

  NAW2003

  HC2005

  NAW2007

  Year

  Figure 22.2. Seat/vote ratios in Wales

  followers to vote for’. Therefore the win set, in a Westminster system, is

  large. This means that the governing party can make radical policy

  changes in any direction it likes, so long as it controls its own MPs and the

  House of Lords does not veto the change. Coalition government contracts the win set, because a majority requires support from more than

  one party. As a consequence, policy is more stable. Stability is neither

  good nor bad in itself, but merely a characteristic of the parliamentary

  setting. In their cross-national survey of the impact of constitutions on

  policy, Persson and Tabellini calculate that proportional regimes spend

  more on welfare policy and have higher budget deficits than majoritarian

  regimes such as the UK parliament. This, they argue, is because under PR

    

  

  there are more veto players who could veto any reduction of welfare benefits for their client groups.11

  However, the situation in Scotland and Wales is more complicated.

  Both countries had new powers in 1999 to do things they could not do

  before. Therefore there could have been majorities that were suppressed

  before 1997, which could change policy radically even under a coalition government. In Scotland, there were. The Scottish Parliament has

  power to alter Scots law on domestic matters, and in some notable

  areas it has done so. It has abolished feudalism and ‘poinding and

  warrant sales’ (a form of recovery of assets from debtors). And it

  has established the right to roam in the countryside.12 On the other

  hand, in the face of homophobic hostility, it ducked the opportunity to

  legislate for civil partnerships in Scotland, passing the parcel hastily to

  Westminster, which enacted a Scottish section in the Civil Partnerships

  Act 2004.

  Policy initiatives in Wales have been more limited – by the National

  Assembly’s powers among other things. The hurried design of the new

  institutions was radically faulty. The primary legislation / secondary legis-

  lation distinction completely fails to map on to the reserved powers /

  devolved powers distinction. Therefore, the Assembly lacks the legal

  power to do a lot of the things its majority might like to. The Assembly’s

  Richard Commission recommended granting more powers to the

  National Assembly. The Government of Wales Act 2006 (2006 c.32),13 a

  notable constitutional statute hardly noticed outside Wales, does some of

  this with effect from the National Assembly taking office in 2007. It abolishes the ‘county council’ model for Welsh government in the 1998 Act,

  and substitutes a ‘government and opposition’ model. It empowers the

  National Assembly to make quasi-Acts (‘Assembly Measures’) in the areas

  for which it is responsible. Devolution, as Ron Davies was fond of saying,

  is a process not an event, and the process will continue beyond the 2007

  election in unpredictable ways.

  11 Torsten Persson and Guido Tabellini, The Economic Effects of Constitutions (Cambridge,

  MA: MIT Press, 2005), tables 6.4 and 6.7.

  12 Abolition of Feudal Tenure etc. (Scotland) Act 2000 asp 5; Abolition of Poindings and

  Warrant Sales Act 2001 asp 1; Land Reform (Scotland) Act 2003 asp 2.

  13 See the Assembly government’s website explaining the Act at http://new.wales.gov.uk/

  gowasub/gowa/?langϭen. For the Richard Commission on the Powers and Electoral

  Arrangements of the National Assembly for Wales (2004) and the former ‘county

  council’ model, see http://image.guardian.co.uk/sys-files/Politics/documents/2004/03/

  31/richard_commission.pdf and the Constitution Unit’s Wales monitoring reports for

  2004 and 2005.

  

   

  However, over most of the domestic agenda, the changes made are

  more incremental than the abolition of feudalism and of poindings. And

  some important developments have been non-changes, where policy has

  changed in England.

  The biggest incremental changes in Scotland have been two expensive

  spending commitments: the non-adoption of ‘top-up’ fees for university

  students domiciled in Scotland and the provision of free social care for

  the elderly. Both of these followed independent reports and were supported by coalition majorities.14 They confirm Persson and Tabellini’s

  claim that coalition government is associated with higher welfare spending. The Scots did both of these because they could: their formula

  funding, examined below, allowed up to 20% per head more spending on

  domestic services than in England.

  Otherwise, policy change has arisen because the Scots and Welsh have

  not made changes that have been made in England. Neither Scotland nor

  Wales has league tables of school or hospital results, nor of local authority performance. Neither has introduced the quasi-market reforms of

  the NHS introduced in England during the second Blair administration

  (see chapter 18). On the whole, the results of policy divergence must

  be highly satisfying to Tony Blair. In England there has been much pain

  and many complaints from the providers of health and education. But,

  if the measurements can be trusted, standards have risen. Waiting

  times have dropped sharply, and school results have improved. In education, it is difficult to make comparisons, just because the Scots and

  Welsh have refused to publish league tables. But in health, they have

  stood still or gone backwards, even though more is spent per head on

  health in Wales and Scotland than in England as a whole, and (in

  Scotland) more than in any region of England except London. Victims of

  these disparities include National Assembly Health Minister Jane Hutt,

  although her sacking in 2005 was not directly linked to the relative failure<
br />
  of the NHS in Wales,15 and three successive chief executives of the Welsh

  14 The (Scottish) Cubie Report on student finance, and the (UK) report of the Sutherland

  Royal Commission on social care, both published in 1999. The UK government rejected

  Sutherland’s recommendation to make social care free for those whose medical condition

  required it, but the Scottish Executive accepted it. See Rachel Simeon, ‘Free Personal Care:

  Policy Divergence and Social Citizenship’, in Robert Hazell (ed.), The State of the Nations

  2003: The Third Year of Devolution in the United Kingdom (Exeter: Imprint Academic,

  2003), pp. 215–35. For full details of both policies, see the Scottish monitoring reports of

  the Constitution Unit.

  15 John Osmond (ed.), Labour’s Majority in Doubt: Monitoring the National Assembly

  December 2004 to April 2005 (Cardiff: IWA, and London: Constitution Unit, 2005), p. 10.

    

  

  Ambulance Service, who resigned or were dismissed in quick succession

  in 2006.16

  The two ‘wicked issues’ of devolution are finance and representation

  in the House of Commons. Before devolution, Scotland, Wales and

  Northern Ireland were each funded by a block grant from the UK

  Treasury. Since the early 1970s, this has been by way of the now-notorious ‘Barnett formula’. It takes its name from Joel (Lord) Barnett, who was

  Chief Secretary to the Treasury from 1974 to 1979, although the Treasury

  was already using it under the previous Conservative government.

  Barnett served two purposes. It substituted a block grant for annual bargaining over each and every service, which the Treasury suspected the

  ‘Celts’ of using to force public spending up to an unacceptable level. In

  this they were backed by their territorial Secretaries of State as part of

  killing Home Rule by kindness. And it was designed to bring very gradual

  convergence towards equal public spending per head for each territory of

  the UK. In 1976 the Treasury also conducted a ‘needs assessment’ with the

  grudging agreement of the territorial departments. This showed that

  Scotland and Northern Ireland, but not Wales, were receiving public

  spending allocations for the services that would have been devolved

  under the (abortive) Scotland and Wales Bill(s) ahead of their ‘needs’.

  In the short run Barnett protects this relative overspending (although

  if the Treasury’s numbers were reliable it should never have been applied

  to Wales). Therefore it made sense for the Constitutional Convention to

  say that it should continue. Its continuation was promised in the White

  Papers preceding the 1998 Scotland and Wales Acts, but is not in the Acts

  themselves, so it could be altered without legislation. In the long run, it

  would cause spending in Scotland and Wales to crash down below whatever their relative needs now are to a level equal per head to spending in

  England. This would not be fair, and would not be in the interests of

  either Wales or Scotland.17

  In the long run, as Keynes said, we are all dead. However, the long run

  has not yet arrived. Barnett has been running for thirty years. But the

  16 ‘Ambulance Reform “to Cost £140m”’, BBC Wales, 26 September 2006, at

  http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/wales/5378974.stm; Wales Audit Office, ‘Ambulance Services

  in Wales’, December 2006, www.wao.gov.uk/assets/englishdocuments/Ambulance_

  Inquiry.pdf. For a book-length discussion of relative performance to 2003, see Scott Greer,

  Territorial Politics and Health Policy: UK Health Policy in Comparative Perspective

  (Manchester: Manchester University Press, 2004).

  17 This is a brutally concise summary. A whole book can be, and has been, written about the

  Barnett formula: Iain McLean, The Fiscal Crisis of the United Kingdom (Basingstoke:

  Palgrave, 2005).

  

   

  Table 22.4. UK identifiable expenditure and relative GVA by country

  and region, per head, 2005–6, excluding social protection

  Region

  £ per head

  Index (UKϭ)

  Index GVA

  Scotland

  5,093

  119.9

  96

  Wales

  4,648

  109.4

  78

  Northern Ireland

  5,457

  128.4

  80

  England:

  4,099

  96.5

  102

  North-east

  4,530

  106.6

  79

  North-west

  4,415

  103.9

  88

  Yorks and

  4,109

  96.7

  87

  Humberside

  E. Midlands

  3,648

  85.9

  93

  W. Midlands

  3,947

  92.9

  89

  E. England

  3,475

  81.8

  107

  London

  5,288

  124.5

  136

  South-east

  3,578

  84.2

  115

  South-west

  3,747

  88.2

  94

  UK

  4,249

  100.0

  100

  Source:

  Cols. 1 and 2: Public Expenditure Statistical Analysis (London: HM Treasury

  2007), calculated from table 9.11.

  Col. 3: Office of National Statistics, Headline Gross Value Added (GVA) at

  current prices by region.

  Correlation between col. 2 and col. 3 Ϫ0.05.

  latest public spending relativities, published by the Treasury in March

  2007, show that Scotland still has public expenditure per head on

  devolved services18 almost 20% ahead of the UK average (table 22.4).

  Wales has spending about 9% ahead of the UK average. But Wales is a relatively poor region and Scotland has roughly average income per head. If

  spending were designed to counter poverty, one would expect the correlation between public spending per head (table 22.4, col. 2) and gross value

  added (GVA) per head (col. 3) to be strongly negative – approaching Ϫ1.

  18 Table 22.4 excludes ‘social protection’, most of which comprises pensions and social security benefits. These are not devolved and are payable at uniform rates throughout the UK.

  Some other identifiable expenditure, notably part of that on agriculture and fisheries, is

  not controlled by the devolved administrations, but exclusion of that does not materially

  affect table 22.4.

    

  

  In fact it is Ϫ0.05. There is almost no correlation between the wealth of a

  UK region and the public spending it gets. Scotland had ample cushion,

  and Wales had a little, to increase welfare spending compared to England,

  as Persson and Tabellini predict.

  The problem of representation has been acidly called ‘what those with

  short memories call the West Lothian Question’.19 Gladstone, who had a

  long memory, wrestled with it for seven years and failed to find an answer

  in either of his Government of Ireland Bills (1886 and 1893). The

  problem is: how (if at all) should a te
rritory which has a devolved government be represented in the House of Commons? If every territory had

  devolution, the problem would be simple. But England does not, and the

  attempt to offer an elected assembly in the north-east was turned down

  overwhelmingly in a referendum in 2004. The House of Commons therefore doubles as the elected part of the government of the UK and of the

  government of England. How many MPs from Scotland and Wales

  should sit there, and what powers should they have?

  One possibility would be to exclude them. But that would not be fair.

  Scotland and Wales are not independent countries. Taxation, social security, foreign affairs and defence are not devolved. For the people of

  Scotland and Wales to be excluded would be taxation without representation – the slogan of the rebellious American colonists in 1776.

  Another possibility is what Gladstone called the ‘in and out solution’ –

  that Scottish and Welsh MPs could vote on non-devolved matters such as

  defence and social security, but not on devolved matters such as health

  and education. This is current Conservative policy. But it is unworkable.

  Whenever the UK party majority in the House of Commons differed

  from the English party majority, the government of the day would be

  unable to carry half its legislation. Either it would be formed by the party

  with a majority of seats in England, which could not tax or run foreign

  affairs; or it would be formed by the party with a UK majority, which

  could not carry its English health or education measures.

  A possible solution to the West Lothian Question is to reduce the

  numbers but not the powers of MPs from Scotland and Wales. This has

  been done in a minor way for Scotland but not for Wales. Scotland has

  come down from seventy-two MPs to fifty-nine, which is only slightly

  above its population share. Wales has forty, which is far above its population share. Northern Ireland was reduced to about two-thirds of its population share of MPs between 1920 and 1979 because it had a devolved

  19 By the constitutional lawyer and Northern Ireland specialist Brigid Hadfield.

  

   

  assembly. But when devolution there ended, its under-representation

  ended too. On none of the occasions since then when devolution was

  restored there, including the latest time in 2007, has anybody dared

  mention the idea of cutting its Westminster representation back again.

  Were this Northern Ireland solution to be again adopted, its representation in the Commons would be cut to about twelve, that of Scotland to

  about forty, and of Wales to about twenty-four.

 

‹ Prev