The Predictioneer’s Game: Using the Logic of Brazen Self-Interest to See and Shape the Future
Page 29
I am particularly grateful for the support of the Alexander Hamilton Center for Political Economy at NYU—The Predictioneer’s Game is the embodiment of its commitment to logic and evidence in pursuit of solutions to policy problems—and to Shinasi Rama, its deputy director, and to those whose generous support makes the Center possible, especially the Veritas Fund, the Thomas W. Smith Foundation, the Lehrman Institute, David Desrosiers, James Piereson, and especially Roger Hertog, without whom there could not be an Alexander Hamilton Center.
My colleagues in the Wilf Family Department of Politics at New York University and at the Hoover Institution at Stanford University are an endless source of support and inspiration. I could not have asked for better environments in which to pursue my research. Random House has been a terrific organization to work with, providing superb and subtle copyediting and bringing the highest standards to every aspect of this work. I thank them for their help.
Finally, I want to remember Kenneth Organski, my professor, coauthor, and friend, and the inspiration behind the original decision to apply my forecasting model to problems in the real world. He died too soon, but he left a legacy that will endure forever.
Appendix I
CALCULATION OF THE WEIGHTED MEAN PREDICTION FOR NORTH KOREA
The table below shows detailed data for some of the fifty-six stakeholders in the North Korean nuclear game, and it provides the summary values for influence times salience (that is, power) and also for influence times salience times position for all of the players. The column I × S × P is summed and divided by the sum of the column for I × S. That is, the weighted mean position equals 1,757,649 ÷ 29,384 = 59.8. This number is approximately equal to the position designated as “Slow reduction, U.S. grants diplomatic recognition.”
A SAMPLE OF DATA, WITH THE CALCULATION OF THE WEIGHTED MEAN POSITION
Appendix II
DATA USED TO ENGINEER A COMPLEX LITIGATION
Afterword to the Paperback Edition
Here we are, just about one year since The Predictioneer’s Game first went to press. A lot has been going on in the world since then, giving us a terrific opportunity to look back and see how the forecasting model did. Of course, it will be much more convincing if you go back over the book’s predictions, as well as forecasts I have made online in speeches, podcasts, and so forth, and judge for yourself. There is always the danger that I will unwittingly focus on the best of my predictions and give less credence to those that were wrong, but I will certainly try not to do that. Besides, you can take the model out for a test drive yourself. Just go to www.predictioneersgame.com and click on the game page. You will have the opportunity to use the apprentice version of the model with your own data sets. There’s also a training manual on the game page to help you understand how to build inputs for the model. You won’t get the full output, just the parts intended for prediction rather than engineering, but you should have considerable fun playing with it, and you’ll be able to keep track of your own accuracy as a predictioneer. And if you are a professor teaching a course that can use the model, then you can register for a fuller version online.
Besides being able to play the game yourself, you are going to have the opportunity to understand more about how it works. You’ll get to look under the hood as well as kick the proverbial tires (sorry for all the car talk, but then, I did offer advice on how to buy a car). Some readers are gluttons for punishment. They don’t want to pick up my (admittedly boring) academic publications to find out the nuts and bolts behind my models. They want it here and they want it now. Okay, I’ll provide some of those details as an appendix to this epilogue so that those who really don’t want to look at equations needn’t be bothered and those who do want to look at some math will—hopefully—be satisfied. This just isn’t the place to go into full detail.
Now, back to the predictions and claims of the book. Let’s start with the approach I suggested for buying a car. That’s not strictly derived from the forecasting model, but it is based on the strategic thinking at the heart of game theory. Some readers have tried my method out and reported on their results, and so far all are positive. Paul Daugherty, who happens to be a journalist, was an admitted skeptic. He tried the method and wrote up the results in The Irish Times on October 28, 2009. I’ll let him do the talking:
So, we put it to the test: our goal was to see what sort of discount we could get if we tested the market for a Ford Mondeo 1.8 petrol saloon with around 50,000 miles on the clock, preferably in metallic silver for less than €9,000.
I pitched my wits against the car dealers of Ireland, trying to buy a car the Bruce Bueno de Mesquita way.
Picking out five cars on the Internet that fitted the criteria, I started in Dublin, rang the first dealership on my list and gave the salesperson the following spiel.
“Hello, my name is Paul O’Doherty, I need to buy a car urgently. At noon tomorrow I will walk into a dealership with cash to buy a 2005 Ford Mondeo 1.8 petrol saloon with around 50,000 miles on the clock from the dealer who offers me the best price. You are the first person I’ve rung and I have four others on my list. What’s your best price?” … Lastly I rang a Kildare dealer with an opening price of €6,900. Delivering what I had to say, the best price returned was €6,750 with the final warning that this price wouldn’t be beaten. And, in fairness, it wasn’t.
Summing up, the Bruce Bueno de Mesquita way certainly cut through a lot of the haggling and allowed me to sidestep the obvious “well, how much are you offering?” or “you’ll have to call in and see us.”
It also got me to the nitty-gritty of price much faster, and all from the comfort of my own home, saving in one case €2,450 off the opening price.
Not bad for less than 10 minutes’ work on the phone.
Mr. Daugherty is not the only one to report success. During an interview on Michael Krasny’s National Public Radio show Forum, a caller who said he had used the car-buying method claimed to have saved $2,000. Krasny also acknowledged having used the method (though he said he had done so before reading the book) and said he believed he had saved $1,000. If you’re going to buy a car, please try my method and send me a comment to post on the book’s website.
Car buying is one thing; accurately predicting big national security issues is another. In Chapter 10 you saw me daring to be embarrassed, making predictions that were about the future at the time when I was originally writing that chapter. Now we can look back over the last few months of 2009 and the first quarter of 2010 to see how I did. Let’s start with developments in Pakistan.
I raised three pretty big questions about how Pakistan’s policy was likely to unfold. They were:
How willing would the Pakistani government be to pursue militant groups operating in and around Pakistan, including al-Qaeda, the Pakistani Taliban, and the Afghan Taliban?
Will the Pakistani government allow U.S. military forces to use Pakistani territory to launch efforts to track down militants?
What level of U.S. foreign aid to Pakistan was likely to change the Pakistani leadership’s approach to pursuing militants?
Within the context of these big-picture issues, the game was used to make several more detailed predictions. Here’s a list (with page references) of those predictions, accompanied by brief accounts of what has happened:
PREDICTION (on this page): The Zardari government, without support from Sharif, would depose Musharraf in June or July 2008.
OUTCOME: The Zardari government actually forced Musharraf to step down in August.
PREDICTION (on this page): The militants and the Pakistani government would negotiate an accommodation. After June 2008 the government would pay only lip service to going after the militants, and the Bush administration would prove unable to change its mind in the absence of a fundamental shift in foreign aid policy.
OUTCOME: There is scant evidence of a concerted effort by the Zardari government to fight the militants in the latter half of 2008. There was a brief military offensive agai
nst the Taliban begun on June 28, which ended in early July with one militant killed. After that, although the Taliban aggressively pursued expansion, the government did little in response. Rather than fight the militants, the government made a deal with the Taliban in February 2009, paying them about $6 million and agreeing to the imposition of Sharia law in the Swat Valley in exchange for the Taliban agreeing to an indefinite ceasefire. The ceasefire unraveled in May. The model did not address how long the agreement would last but did correctly foresee that the two sides would strike a deal after a half year of seeming Pakistani indifference toward the militant threat.
PREDICTION (on this page): The Pakistani military would decline in power faster than the government. This was predicted to produce a heightened risk of a coup between February and June 2009. The model also predicted that by midsummer a coup would become unlikely.
OUTCOME: Although there was talk of a potential coup to bring Zardari down and that talk continued into the fall of 2009, no coup was launched and Zardari remains in power with no current hints that the military is trying to depose him. This is consistent with the model’s conditional forecast (if no coup, then …).
PREDICTION (on this page): The U.S. government would switch from its two-pronged approach—clandestine pursuit of militants by the United States and open pursuit of militants by the Pakistani government—to greater emphasis on direct use of the American military in Pakistan.
OUTCOME: U.S. drone attacks against Taliban and al-Qaeda targets in Pakistan have experienced a tremendous upsurge and are no longer treated as clandestine. Indeed, the U.S. military has allowed American TV broadcasts showing drones being controlled remotely from military bases in the United States. The U.S. government seems to be continuing, as well, to use American armed forces inside Pakistan’s borders. In early February 2010, three Americans were killed in a Pakistani roadside bombing, drawing attention to the barely acknowledged role of the U.S. military in training and otherwise assisting against the Taliban and al-Qaeda. These outcomes echo the model’s predictions. As we will see, the timing of changes in Pakistan’s approach to militants is also consistent with the model’s expectations.
PREDICTION (on this page): If the United States provided the Pakistani government with $1.5 billion in aid (while looking the other way regarding some misappropriation of the aid by Pakistani leaders), then the Pakistani government and military would aggressively pursue militants inside its borders but would not be so aggressive as to shut down the militants completely. Doing so would, after all, put the flow of aid dollars at risk.
OUTCOME: The Kerry-Lugar aid bill was passed at the end of September 2009. It allocated $1.5 billion to Pakistan, tripling aid from its level one year earlier. The bill contained strong language restricting how the Pakistani government could use the money and required an accounting of expenditures. The Pakistani government balked at taking the aid. Senator John Kerry clarified that the bill was not designed to interfere at all with sovereign Pakistani decisions; that is, he essentially assured the Pakistani leadership that the United States would not closely monitor use of the funds. Shortly afterward, the Pakistani government greatly stepped up its pursuit of militants operating within its borders. By February 2010 they had captured the number two Taliban leader, but so far they have certainly not terminated the Taliban’s ability to fight back. This is as predicted.
On the negative side, I presumed, with some evidence within the model’s results, that the U.S. government was unlikely to grant Pakistan $1.5 billion. Still, this was treated as a contingency rather than a firm prediction. The model led to firm predictions under the contingency of less than $1.5 billion in aid (little effort against the militants) and under the contingency of $1.5 billion in aid (significant effort against the militants). The first contingency is consistent with Pakistani efforts prior to passage of the aid bill. The model was accurate regarding the consequences of giving Pakistan $1.5 billion in aid after September 2009, and it is noteworthy that the analysis also led to the conclusion that there was no reason to give Pakistan more than $1.5 billion per year. Congress got that right!
Results out of Pakistan are largely consistent with the model’s predictions, both in terms of the big picture (given that forecasts were made under alternative contingencies) and in terms of lots of nitty-gritty detail. So far, so good!
How about the other big predictions in the chapter “Dare to Be Embarrassed!”? They were about Iran-Iraq relations after the summer of 2010 and were contingent on whether the United States keeps troops in Iraq or fully withdraws. As I am writing in March 2010, we do not yet know which contingency will arise. We will just have to be patient and wait to see what happens during the period covered by the predictions. That, after all, is the point of the chapter. Meanwhile, perhaps some Iran and Iraq specialists would care to put into print what they believe will happen (and why) if the United States stays in or pulls out completely.
Finally, the last chapter discussed what was likely to come out of the Copenhagen summit on climate change. As I was writing the chapter, there was widespread optimism that Copenhagen would be a turning point leading to serious efforts to reduce greenhouse gas emissions. Here are just a few statements on expectations for Copenhagen written roughly around the time when The Predictioneer’s Game was used to evaluate prospects for Copenhagen (and some written even later, when the authors of the reports cited had access to more information with which to form expectations):
“The architecture of the Copenhagen treaty should initiate a race to the top…. Copenhagen has the potential to give the world a clear path to rapidly bending the global emission’s curve—and give millions of people and species a chance at survival.” (World Wildlife Federation, “WWF Expectations for the Copenhagen Climate Deal 2009,” March 2009, www.worldwildlife.org/climate/Publications/WWFBinaryitem12417.pdf)
In a report on German government expectations, Germanwatch reported, “Important and decisive steps have been taken in Bali. They give reason to believe that a new global agreement on climate protection for the time after 2012, i.e. following the expiration of the Kyoto Protocol’s first commitment period, will come into effect.” (“Bali, Poznan, Copenhagen—Triple Jump Towards a New Quality of Climate Policy?,” www.germanwatch.org/klima/bapocoe.htm)
And in a report from Time one year ahead of Copenhagen (Bryan Walsh, “What to Expect from the UN Climate-Change Summit,” December 10, 2008, www.time.com/time/health/article/0,8599,1865767,00.html#ixzz0hPt0sTyl), France’s climate ambassador, Brice Lalonde, said of the then-upcoming Copenhagen summit, “We hope for a spectacular outcome in Copenhagen next year.”
Meanwhile, using data put together by my students, the game’s forecast was for failure at Copenhagen, and that, sadly, is just what we got.
The predictions thus far have been pretty well borne out by subsequent events, so there is not much to be embarrassed about. Rather, the match between predictions and outcomes over the past year may be seen as encouraging to those who believe that through the transparent application of logic and evidence we can anticipate and perhaps influence the course of events for the better.
The model’s success continues to garner the attention of people making high-stakes decisions and is stimulating others to teach game-theory-based political forecasting. The model’s performance and online availability is even helping to bring this particular rational-actor approach into the classroom in new arenas, including graduate programs in social work, psychiatry, and business and in military training. That is most gratifying. With a bit of luck, we may see further integration of a more rational approach to how we understand the decisions and actions of others. Then we may be better able to use that understanding to inform our own decisions, corporate decisions, and decisions in the arena of national security, helping to make the world a more peaceful, more just, and happier place for all of us.
Appendix to the Paperback Edition
Because some of you asked for it:
The figure on this page
illustrates a single stage game for a single pair of players (call them A and B) while not displaying the sources of uncertainty in the model. Nature assigns initial probabilities of 0.5 to player types, and the model then applies Bayes’ Rule so that the players can update their beliefs. There are sixteen possible combinations of beliefs about the mix of player types. Each player is uncertain whether the other player is a hawk or a dove or whether the other player is pacific or retaliatory. By hawk I mean someone who prefers to compel a rival to give in to the hawk’s demands even if this necessitates both imposing and enduring costs rather than compromising on the policy outcome. A dove prefers to compromise rather than engage in costly coercion to get the rival to give in. A retaliatory player prefers to defend himself—at potentially high costs—rather than be bullied into giving in, while a pacific player prefers to give in to avoid further costs.
The game is iterated so that payoffs can change from round to round, with a round defined as a sequence of moves through the stage game in the figure. Because the game is solved for all directional pairs, it assumes that players do not know whether they will be moving first, second, or simultaneously with each other player. The game ends, by assumption, when the sum of player payoffs in an iteration is greater than the projected sum of those payoffs in the next iteration.