Book Read Free

The Downfall of Money: Germany’s Hyperinflation and the Destruction of the Middle Class

Page 18

by Taylor, Frederick


  Month

  Marks to Dollar Rate

  Unemployment (per cent)

  April (1920)

  72

  1.9

  May

  57.5

  2.7

  June

  39.3

  4.0

  July

  37.95

  6.0

  August

  42.25

  5.9

  September

  49.75

  4.5

  October

  61.55

  4.2

  November

  77.87

  3.9

  December

  62.18

  4.1

  January (1921)

  74.72

  4.5

  February

  65.48

  4.7

  March

  60.93

  3.7

  April

  62.55

  3.9

  May

  65.65

  3.7

  June

  63.30

  3.0

  July

  74.92

  2.6

  August

  74.92

  2.2

  September

  84.41

  1.4

  October

  124.37

  1.2

  November

  181.31

  1.4

  December

  217.00

  1.6

  There is evidence that during the late spring/early summer of 1920, foreign customers began to baulk at the international price of German goods; domestic consumers, meanwhile, went on a ‘buyers’ strike’, perhaps in anticipation of even lower prices, but perhaps, because of the hefty price rises that had been imposed during the previous bout of rapid inflation, they really couldn’t afford the goods.2

  As a consequence of the uncomfortable situation that the now-unaccustomed health of the mark caused during the period of May to August 1920, it seems that, in fact, the Finance Ministry and the Reichsbank covertly combined their efforts, not to strengthen the currency but to keep the value of the mark from rising any further.

  The authorities seem to have seen their job as maintaining the exchange rate at what might be dubbed a ‘Goldilocks’ level – not so high as to inhibit exports, not so low as to increase the economic and financial chaos within the Reich itself. More especially, a reasonable exchange rate against foreign currencies was necessary to keep essential imports of food for the working population affordable. The value during most of this time of 60–70 marks to the dollar apparently represented this ‘not too hot, not too cold’ value that the financial elite in Germany favoured.3 In other words, there was no incentive, even at this relatively favourable point, to actively promote the strength of the national currency and thus start to halt and even reverse the unstoppable march of inflation.

  Walther Rathenau, head of the AEG electricals conglomerate founded by his father, heroic co-architect of Germany’s wartime economic effort, bestselling author, and latterly democratic politician, was minuted as having told a meeting at the German Foreign Office in January 1921 that the Anglo-American slump must be prevented from infecting Germany, whatever the cost. The meeting secretary’s note read:

  He was not afraid of inflation, if he might make an aside not strictly relevant to the agenda: should the depression that has attacked England with full force spread across to us, we ought to print money a bit faster and start construction works, using the employment these create as a dam against the depression. It was incorrect when people said that printing money was bringing us to ruin.4

  Fatal words. For the meantime, however, the fragile stability of the mark was maintained. There were two more changes of government in this time. No new elections, but reshufflings of the political pack.

  Fehrenbach’s government collapsed at the beginning of May 1921, when the Allies, meeting in London for the last of seemingly countless post-Versailles conferences, finally presented the big reparations bill that Germany had been kept waiting for since November 1918. It amounted to 132 billion gold marks (around $31.5 billion at pre-war rates). The figure had actually been drastically reduced from an original 269 billion gold marks (around $64 billion) put forward in January 1921. Mind-boggling (and astonishingly variable) as these sums were, everyone took them extremely seriously. Or so it seemed. Certainly, the demand was coupled with an Allied threat to occupy the Ruhr industrial area, should Germany not accept the demand and the payment schedule attached to it.

  Despite the Chancellor’s efforts to persuade the German People’s Party to accept the so-called ‘London Ultimatum’, the Fehrenbach government fell apart as soon as a decision was required. The right-liberals of the German People’s Party could accept the Republic as a reality, they could even serve in one of its governments, but they could not - yet - stomach the reality of accepting the Versailles settlement.

  The curious thing was that, though the language of the Ultimatum was tough – even two and a half years after the end of the war, there were still those angry French and British voters to think about – its substance, when properly examined, was much less so.

  The reparations payment schedule, for instance, divided the payment of German liabilities between three sets of bonds: A, B and C bonds. The A bonds represented the unpaid balance of the 20 billion marks that Germany was supposed to have paid since 1919, but hadn’t. The B bonds were to cover war damages. Both bore interest of 6 per cent and totalled 50 billion gold marks. The other 82 billion gold marks were payable via issuing of so-called C bonds, whose role was left a little vague but was thought to have to do with cancellation of inter-Allied debt. The C bonds, however, would be issued only when Germany had proved itself capable of meeting the other obligations (the A and B bonds). These first-priority obligations would be calculated via a formula involving a fixed annual payment (reckoned at 2 billion gold marks) and a variable payment (a British-created imposition called an ‘export levy’) corresponding to 26 per cent of the value of German exports in any given year (at current 1921 levels around 1 billion gold marks). This made, for 1921, an annual German liability of 3 billion or so.

  The almost entirely theoretical nature of the C bonds becomes clear when the actual level of German exports in the straitened, protectionist post-war world economy is taken into account. The average annual level of German exports during 1920–22 was 4.8 billion gold marks. A quarter of that (roughly the amount claimed by the export levy) amounted to around a billion. By one expert calculation, for the issue of C bonds by Germany to be triggered, German exports would have needed to more than quadruple to a total of 22 billion gold marks a year, representing five times current exports and twice what the country had managed to sell abroad even in the highly favourable, liberal peacetime trading conditions of 1913.5 The likelihood of such a number ever being reached was further lessened by the fact that official German government statistics on imports and exports, dependent on figures supplied by businesses, were notoriously unreliable. According to a leading German financial journalist, no less a person than State Secretary Hirsch had admitted this at a meeting:

  . . . imports and exports were being falsified for the purposes of capital flight. Imports are exaggerated with the purpose of more easily permitting the actually unused portion to be kept abroad, and at the same time the exports are set at a lower level for the same purpose: to leave the surplus profit abroad.6

  The trick with the C bonds meant that the Allies had, in fact, reduced the practical German liability to 50 billion gold marks, or even 41 billion gold marks if sums already paid in cash or in kind by Germany since 1919 are taken into account.7 Of the C bonds, the Belgian Prime Minister of the time reputedly jested that the Reparations Commission ‘could stick [the C bonds] in a drawer without bothering to lock it, for no thief would be tempted to steal them’.8

  There were those politicians in Germany who realised immediately that the b
urden, though still unpleasant and to their minds unjust, was nowhere as bad as most of their fellow countrymen and countrywomen had expected. One Centre Party politician remarked at a party meeting just the day after the London Ultimatum that ‘the Entente will only demand the 50 billion marks, not the rest. They have only called for the rest for domestic political reasons.’9

  ‘Domestic political reasons’ cut both ways. The public in the Allied countries saw the 132 billion marks in notional reparations and rejoiced. The public in Germany saw the 132 billions, ignored the technical sleight of hand that drastically reduced their country’s actual liability, at least for the foreseeable future, and was enraged. Neither the Allied governments, who wished to conceal their relative moderation from their voters, nor the German government, keen to exaggerate the impossible economic burden of the demand as part of its long-term campaign to avoid payment, felt it in their interests to tell the truth.

  All the same, however you reckoned the schedule, 50 billion marks was a great deal of money to come up with. Not only that, but the German government had to hand over a billion in an approved foreign currency (dollars, as it turned out, which were still convertible into gold) or acceptable Treasury bills, by the end of August. This demand was met, but only after a hair-raisingly complicated and difficult set of financial manoeuvres that included putting 560 cases of the Reichsbank’s gold on four steamers just before the deadline, hurriedly selling paper marks in huge quantities on the foreign exchange markets, shaming several large corporations into lending the government money from their own extensive foreign exchange holdings, and, through the offices of the Mendelssohn Bank’s representative in the Netherlands, raising more than a quarter of a billion in hard currency loans from a Dutch-British banking consortium.10

  So the government got the money to the Allies in time to avoid default and a possible occupation of the Ruhr, but the procedures it had needed to go through to get the money did not bode well for future cash payments. Moreover, the German government’s sale of so many paper marks within such a short period had spooked the foreign exchange markets, hence ending the period of relative stabilisation in the value of the mark abroad. Germany’s currency declined from around 65 to the dollar in May to 85 in September, with a falling tendency that would further accelerate as autumn came on.

  The horrified, and in many cases violent, reaction of the German public to the Allies’ reparations ultimatum brought enormous political problems for the government that succeeded Fehrenbach’s. The right-liberal German People’s Party had walked out in protest at the settlement, after which Josef Wirth, a younger Centre politician, had put together a coalition with the Social Democrats, who were prepared go through the motions of complying with the Allied ultimatum.

  The psychological effect on the German nation, and on its confidence in the future – not to mention its currency – was severe and lasting. After almost two years of living in a ‘fools’ paradise’, they finally knew (or thought they knew) the sum they would have to pay, and for which they had signed up in June 1919, in effect issuing a blank and post-dated cheque to the Allies.

  In 1806, as almost any German schoolboy – and absolutely any German nationalist – would remind everyone, Prussia had paid a huge indemnity to Napoleon Bonaparte in cash, territory and men. In 1815, with the roles reversed, defeated France had paid hefty reparations to the Allies who beat Napoleon. In 1871, under the Treaty of Frankfurt, France had been forced to pay the new German nation its notorious reparations bill of 5 billion gold francs, a sum precisely calculated on the basis of the 1806 penalty extracted by Napoleon from the defeated Prussians. All these treaties, with their heavy financial penalties for the losers in the wars to which they provided the legal conclusion, stated clearly at the time of signature what indemnities were due. And paid those indemnities were.

  Versailles was the first treaty where reparations were left open-ended, and remained so for a matter of years. Unsurprisingly, under these circumstances, when the Allies’ bill was finally issued, the mark tumbled. It would never again, in its current form, reach a level comparable to that in the spring of 1921. The only way now was down.

  Although Matthias Erzberger had been elected as a member of the Reichstag in June 1920, he was, meanwhile, no longer Finance Minister. He had been forced to resign his post shortly before the Kapp putsch, under circumstances that caused most observers to consider him politically finished.

  Karl Helfferich, the former banker and establishment economic wizard who had blithely told the Reichstag in 1915 that the Allies would have to pay for the war, had moved radically to the right under the influence of defeat and Versailles. He was now a passionate and vocal leader of the anti-republican nationalist opposition. Helfferich had made it his business to bring about the downfall of Erzberger. In his budget speech in July 1919, Erzberger had publicly blamed Helfferich’s allegedly lax behaviour in office as Imperial Treasury Secretary during the war for both the size of Germany’s post-war deficit and the large-scale, unhindered profiteering by arms and munitions contractors. Helfferich responded to these accusations by publishing a broadside, Fort mit Erzberger! (Away with Erzberger!) in which he in return accused the reforming Finance Minister of corrupt relations with big business.

  Erzberger felt compelled to sue Helfferich for libel – it was while emerging from a Berlin court building after one day’s legal proceedings that he was wounded by the would-be assassin, Hirschfeld – but although his persecutor was convicted of a ‘defamatory statement (üble Nachrede), Helfferich was fined only 300 marks. Much of the evidence presented had cast Erzberger in a very unflattering light. Substantial parts of Helfferich’s accusations were considered justified by the court, and in any case he had acted, so the judge said in a remark typical of the judiciary at that time, ‘from patriotic motives’. Meanwhile, the right-wing Hamburger Nachrichten had published leaked copies of Erzberger’s tax returns which also led to suspicions of tax evasion. Erzberger resigned that same day.11

  Since the spring of 1920, Erzberger had assumed a low profile. However, perhaps inevitably for a man of his talent and energy, he was clearly planning a political comeback at some point, an ambition in which he was encouraged by further court rulings that cleared him of tax evasion and various other financial chicanery. With the Reichsbank’s attempts to scrape together the tranche of a billion gold marks demanded by the Allies spread all over the newspapers, and feelings running high on the right against the politicians who had acceded to the London Ultimatum, towards the end of the summer Erzberger left Berlin to take a health cure at Bad Griesbach, a spa in the Black Forest in his native south-west Germany.

  Erzberger was fully aware of the degree of hatred he aroused among German nationalists. He reportedly announced in the spring of 1921 to his daughter, Maria: ‘The bullet that will kill me has already been cast.’12 On 26 August 1921, he set off for his regular morning walk in the woods with a friend and fellow Centre Party politician, Karl Diez. At around eleven o’clock, they came under fire from two armed young men, who had been lying in wait among the trees. Erzberger, seriously wounded, scrambled down a slope in the hope of evading his attackers. Eighteen months earlier, Hirschfeld’s second bullet had been deflected by Erzberger’s watch chain. This time, he was not so lucky. The assassins pursued him relentlessly, raining fire on him until he fell still. They then stood over his body and shot him twice more in the head. It was a brutal, professional ‘hit’.13

  A police hunt was set in motion, and the assassins were rapidly identified, but to no avail. The two young men, both in their late twenties, were named as Heinrich Schulz and Heinrich Tillesen. The first was a former army lieutenant, the second the son of an artillery general and former torpedo boat officer. Both were Freikorps volunteers who had fought with the Erhardt Brigade and taken part in the Kapp putsch the previous year. Both were fanatical nationalists and enemies of the post-war German state.

  Captain Erhardt was directly responsible for the murder of Erzb
erger. After the failure of the March 1920 coup, aware of being a marked man so far as the democratic government in Berlin was concerned, he had dissolved his Freikorps and headed south to the reactionary stronghold of Munich. There he had the protection of powerful friends within the authorities. Once established in Munich, over the next few months he gathered loyal followers around him and set up a conspiratorial group, codenamed Organisation Consul. The group, whose purpose was to murder politicians and public figures considered to have ‘betrayed’ Germany during the war and its aftermath, soon commanded a loose network of branches throughout the country, though Munich remained its nerve centre and place of refuge.

  Schulz and Tillesen were duly selected from among Organisation Consul’s members to kill Erzberger. After the murder, they fled back to Munich. They were quickly supplied with fake passports and spirited away to Hungary, where a ‘white’ terror had replaced the red. Like many other fugitive members of the German far right, they were afforded shelter by sympathetic authorities.14

  The murder of Erzberger showed firstly that the nationalist right was prepared to kill anyone judged to be responsible for the country’s post-war condition (a judgement which was, of course, arrived at entirely according to their political prejudices), but, more shockingly, it also showed that the more mainstream anti-republican elements were prepared, if not to actively participate in such violence, to tolerate, even half condone, it. The venerable Kreuz-Zeitung, mouthpiece of landed Prussian conservatism, compared the killers of Erzberger with Brutus, William Tell, and Charlotte Corday, who in 1793, as France’s revolutionary terror reached its climax, had stabbed the Jacobin demagogue Marat in his bath. The like-minded Berliner Lokalanzeiger wrote, ‘any other country would extend boundless understanding to such conspirators’, and in East Prussia – heartland of the Kapp putsch – another local newspaper proclaimed that ‘we must sow hatred’:

 

‹ Prev