Book Read Free

BLAIR’S BRITAIN, 1997–2007

Page 30

by ANTHONY SELDON (edt)


  he seems to have taken some time to grasp its full implications. In 1999,

  Blair berated Paddy Ashdown, the Liberal leader, for the policies the

  Liberal Democrats were pursuing on student support in Scotland, which

  were contrary to those being pursued by the government at Westminster.

  ‘You can’t have Scotland doing something different from the rest of the

  country’, Blair complained.

  ‘Then you shouldn’t have given the Scots devolution’, Ashdown retorted,

  ‘specifically, the power to be different on this issue. You put yourself in a

  ridiculous position if, having produced the legislation to give power to the

  Scottish Parliament, you then say it is a matter of principle they can’t use it.’

  Tony Blair (laughing): ‘Yes, that is a problem. I am beginning to see the

  defects in all this devolution stuff.’18

  Yet, if the Scottish Parliament were to follow exactly the same policies as

  those pursued at Westminster, it might be wondered why it should be set

  up in the first place.

  Social democracy presupposed a strong state and a centralised state.

  That was why it had been opposed by leading figures on Labour’s left,

  such as Aneurin Bevan, who, when establishing the National Health

  Service, rigorously set his face against any separate Welsh, Scottish or

  Northern Irish Health Service. It was to be a National Health Service, and

  its benefits would be provided on the basis of need and not of geography.

  That was also the reason why devolution had been opposed in the 1970s

  by Neil Kinnock, who then regarded himself as Bevan’s disciple, and

  declared in 1976 that devolution ‘could be an obituary notice for this

  movement’.19 ‘We shall’, Kinnock argued in 1978, ‘be introducing into all

  18 Paddy Ashdown: The Ashdown Diaries, vol. II: 1997–1999 (Harmondsworth: Allen

  Lane/Penguin, 2001), p. 446, 7 May 1999.

  19 Labour Party Conference, 1976, cited in Miles Taylor, ‘Labour and the Constitution’, in

  Duncan Tanner, Pat Thane and Nick Tiratsoo (eds.), Labour’s First Century (Cambridge:

  Cambridge University Press, 2000), p. 180.

  

   

  political considerations an argument that has barely figured at all in

  British political dialogues and discussions – We have had divisions on a

  class basis, but not on a geographic or nationalistic basis.’20

  For social democrats, only a strong centralised state could evaluate the

  needs of different social groups and ensure that redistribution was

  effective. But devolution would fragment the power of the centralised state

  and cut it into pieces. There could not, in the ideology of social democracy,

  be a separate Scottish or Welsh political will; for the problems of securing

  equality in Scotland or in Wales were no different in nature from the problems of securing it in England. These problems should be resolved not by

  establishing toy-town parliaments in Edinburgh and Cardiff, but only by a

  strong social democratic government at Westminster.

  The consequences, less than a decade after the Scottish Parliament and

  the National Assembly of Wales have been established, would have confirmed Aneurin Bevan’s worst fears. In a number of areas of public

  policy – residential care for the elderly, the cost of prescriptions, student

  support, city academies, foundation hospitals – the dispensation in

  Scotland and Wales is quite different from that in England. The Scottish

  and Welsh devolved bodies have chosen to be more generous than

  Westminster; they have decided not to adopt city academies, foundation

  hospitals or top-up fees; they have been, it might be said, Old Labour

  rather than New Labour.

  Yet, far from seeking to counteract these trends, the Blair government,

  in its final days, sought to emphasise the theme of devolution, arguing

  that it should now be applied to England, though in a different form from

  the ill-fated regional assemblies proposed for the North-East in 2004, and

  rejected in a referendum. The Blair government proposed ‘double devolution’ in England, devolution not merely to local authorities, but also to

  local electors who would be encouraged to use new instruments of direct

  participation in order to overcome what many Blairites saw as a crisis of

  disengagement in British democracy.21 Whatever the merits of such a

  programme, it would be likely, if carried out, to increase geographical

  inequalities in England, not to mitigate them. It therefore runs counter

  to social democracy as traditionally understood, and even to the New

  Liberalism of the early twentieth century, which also sought to equalise

  welfare opportunities between those living in different parts of the

  20 House of Commons Debates, 5th series, vol. 941, c. 1540, 10 January 1978.

  21 See Geoff Mulgan and Fran Bury, Double Devolution: The Renewal of Local Government

  (London: Smith Institute, 2006).

   

  

  country. It has much more in common with the Old Liberalism of

  W. E. Gladstone, a devolutionist but a strong opponent of all forms of

  social democracy, redistribution and state action in the economy, which

  he slightingly termed ‘construction’, than with contemporary political

  doctrines.

  In his Fabian pamphlet, The Third Way, Tony Blair claimed that the

  main aim of social democracy was the promotion of ‘social justice with

  the state as its main agent’.22 It is difficult, however, to see how the state

  can promote social justice if it has been fragmented and cut into pieces by

  devolution.

  IV

  What, then, remains of social democracy after ten years of Tony Blair?

  What has been the Blair effect? What is there that has been ‘New’ about

  New Labour? Tony Blair applied the epithet primarily to Labour’s new

  approach to reform of the public services. For the party seemed imprisoned in an old-fashioned mindset according to which the public sector

  was inherently good and the private sector inherently bad. New Labour

  sought to escape this crude dichotomy. The essence of New Labour was

  that public services needed to use the techniques of private business and

  the market to increase efficiency. Injections of new money into the public

  services, therefore, were to be dependent upon reform. Moreover, the

  state should no longer be expected to be the sole provider of public services. Thus, while schooling and treatment under the National Health

  Service were to remain free at source, the business sector would be

  encouraged to finance new schools – city academies – for the state sector,

  particularly in the run-down inner cities; while foundation hospitals

  would be allowed, and indeed encouraged, to use contracts with private

  bodies to improve their services.

  It is, however, somewhat odd to call all this ‘new’. It is new only for

  those on the left. For the Thatcher and Major governments had already

  shown that public services might be best run by a mixture of private and

  private money, and that the state should no longer be a monopoly

  provider. These doctrines were new, therefore, only for the Labour Party.

  There is, h
owever, just one area where Blair can claim to have rejuvenated social democracy. It lies in the massive increase in public expenditure, especially on the NHS, after 2001. This led to the first increase in the

  22 Tony Blair, The Third Way (London: Fabian Society, 1998), p. 1.

  

   

  public sector share of gross domestic product since the 1970s, the last

  period of Labour government. It had been made possible by Gordon

  Brown’s prudential economic policies from 1997 to 2001, policies which

  had gained the confidence of the financial markets, and therefore allowed

  expansion of the public services to occur safely. The increase in public

  expenditure constituted a radical break with the policies of the Thatcher

  and Major governments, and it has transformed even the attitude of the

  Conservative Party to the public services. For, at the time of writing, David

  Cameron, the Conservative leader, is insisting that the Conservatives

  would follow a ‘prudent’ policy in government. By this he means that they

  would ensure that the public services were fully protected before embarking upon any programme of tax cuts. Maintaining standards in the public

  services would be the most important priority. Such a stance offers a striking contrast to the position taken by Margaret Thatcher as opposition

  leader in the 1970s, although of course tax rates were much higher then

  than they are today. It is possible, nevertheless, that the increases in public

  expenditure since 2001 will permanently shift the terms of political

  debate, so that the mark of prudence in a government will no longer be

  that it seeks to hold taxes down, but that it maintains expenditure on the

  public services.

  Apart from this, perhaps important change, however, it is difficult to

  point to any other ways in which Blair has been able to breathe life into

  the dry bones of social democracy. This does not mean that he has not

  achieved good things in government; and it would be wrong to suggest

  that Blair’s vision of social democracy, the ‘Third Way’, or any of the

  other sobriquets which it has been given, is merely a clever soundbite,

  designed to hide the fact that his policies have been essentially a continuation of those of the Thatcher and Major governments. Blair has tried

  hard to humanise the neo-liberal economy which he inherited. When

  John Major became Prime Minister in 1990, he indicated that he wanted

  to make Britain a country at ease with itself after the radicalism of the

  Thatcher years. Blair has sought to do the same, and has perhaps done

  more to help achieve this aim. For he has emphasised, to a far greater

  extent than the Conservatives did, the problem of social exclusion, and

  has sought new and more sophisticated policy instruments to combat it.

  There is some difficulty in evaluating the success of these instruments,

  however, since many of them – and, in particular, the measures taken to

  improve education and training – will yield their results only in the long

  term, and not over a period of one, or even three, parliaments. Moreover,

  under the Blair government, the trend towards greater inequality of

   

  

  incomes, apparent under the Conservatives, appears to have been halted.

  Nevertheless, the central concern of the Blair government has been not

  with securing relative equality between different social groups, but with

  combating social exclusion, a very different thing.

  Thus it is only when seen from the standpoint of a demoralised left that

  Blair can be said to have rejuvenated social democracy. Seen from any

  other standpoint, New Labour may be regarded as a form of accommodation, designed to hide from those on the left the extent to which the party

  was accepting the new settlement built by Margaret Thatcher and John

  Major. Perhaps this is not Tony Blair’s fault. For it may be the case that

  there is no longer, and has not been for some time, a real social democratic alternative to the Thatcher/Major settlement.

  Political scientists are accustomed to distinguish between ‘position’

  politics and ‘valence’ politics.23 The ‘position’ politics of conflict between

  alternatives is a much rarer phenomenon in British politics than is sometimes thought. It was present, no doubt, in 1945 and 1979, and in 1983,

  the year of Labour’s most catastrophic post-war defeat. Since then it

  has come to be replaced by ‘valence’ politics, a politics based upon agreement about ends, but disagreement about means. ‘In our view’, argue the

  leading students of elections in Britain, ‘the most important factor

  underlying electoral choice is valence – people’s judgments of the overall

  competence of the rival political parties’.24 There has been, since 1992,

  broad agreement that the fundamental framework established by

  Margaret Thatcher, based on privatisation, a liberal economy and a weakened trade union movement, should be maintained. The point at issue at

  general elections since 1992 has been which party would administer that

  dispensation most effectively.

  Tony Blair’s essential skill has been to transform position politics

  into valence politics. For, where Labour had taken up a position in clear

  opposition to that of the Conservatives, that position had often been

  electorally unpopular. Blair insisted, therefore, that a Labour government would not run the economy in a radically different way from the

  Conservatives, but would run it more competently; he insisted that a

  Labour government would not restore the powers of the trade unions by

  reversing the legislation of the Thatcher years putting them under statutory control; he insisted that a Labour government would nationalise

  23 See Donald Stokes, ‘Valence Politics’, in Dennis Kavanagh (ed.), Electoral Politics (Oxford:

  Clarendon Press, 1992), pp. 141–64.

  24 Harold Clarke, David Sanders, Marianne C. Stewart and Paul Whiteley, Political Choice in

  Britain (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2004), p. 9.

  

   

  nothing. Indeed, the general election of 1997 was the first since the

  Labour Party had been formed in which nationalisation was not an election issue. The issue, rather, was what Labour would privatise, not what it

  would nationalise. It was not unfair for Douglas Hurd to say, that ‘the

  Conservatives lost the 1997 election, having won the fundamental arguments’.25 Tony Blair won elections not through a radical upsurge from

  below, but because he was perceived as a more competent leader than his

  opponents, and a leader, moreover, who would not disturb the gains that

  had been achieved during the period of Conservative government. Tony

  Blair, like Harold Macmillan, proved himself a master of the politics of a

  post-ideological age. Both succeeded in accommodating their parties to

  uncomfortable realities, even if the methods they chose were very

  different. But Tony Blair was also a master of the politics of a post-social

  democratic age.

  The emasculation of social democracy followed inevitably from Blair’s

  acceptance of the constraint of globalisation, a ‘golden straitjacket’ as the

  American commentator Thomas Friedman has called it.26 For soc
ial

  democracy has always been a doctrine whose fundamental premise was

  that the processes of economic and social change could be controlled by

  government. Globalisation has, for the time being at least, undermined

  that premise, narrowing if not eliminating entirely scope for the politics

  of redistribution. The social democratic doctrine of the primacy of

  politics has been replaced by the neo-liberal doctrine of the primacy of

  economics.

  There is of course no inherent reason why this new dispensation

  should prove permanent any more than the post-war Attlee settlement

  was to prove permanent. Perhaps the future will show that the postThatcherite settlement is just as impermanent, or perhaps an original and

  creative social democrat thinker will arise to formulate a new social

  democratic doctrine, to show a path forward for social democrats in a

  globalised world. But the Blair effect, while thoroughly beneficent in so

  many areas of public policy, has done little to controvert the proposition

  that social democracy no longer constitutes an effective doctrine for a

  modern government.

  25 Douglas Hurd, ‘His Major Achievements’, Daily Telegraph, 30 June 1997, p. 18.

  26 Cited in Sheri Berman, The Primacy of Politics: Social Democracy and the Making of

  Europe’s Twentieth Century (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2006), p. 209.

  PA RT I I

  Economics and finance

  10

  The Treasury and economic policy

   

  Preliminaries

  What was Tony Blair’s economic legacy? Inferring the economic effects of

  government policy is never an easy task. We need to ask how things would

  have differed had policies been different. Posing that counterfactual faces

  challenges. There are many other influences on events, apart from what

  government does. Economic entities depend on choices made by countless households and firms, and these in turn reflect their resources, technologies, unobservable expectations and beliefs about future policy (and

  other aspects of their environment). None of these are set in stone. Then

  there is the speed of impact. Sometimes economic policy has quick

  effects. And some variables can overreact. Often, though, repercussions

 

‹ Prev