Book Read Free

BLAIR’S BRITAIN, 1997–2007

Page 31

by ANTHONY SELDON (edt)


  take many years to work out in full. This is especially true of government

  decisions that influence the supply side of the economy. Add to this the

  fact that figures we have for many of the key economic variables are measured with error and subject to regular revision. So the economic record

  for a recent period that we have to hand now may be seriously inaccurate,

  distorted by a host of other factors, and barely affected by what governments did or did not do within that interval.

  Politicians claim credit when things go well. They seek scapegoats to

  exculpate themselves when they do not. So their own statements, and the

  briefings and announcements of their news managers, may give no sound

  basis for judgement. (Nor can we trust opposition parties, given their role

  to paint a picture in the bleakest hues.) There is a further problem, too.

  Government has many heads. The formal constitutional position may be

  clear (although often it is not). But how are we to assign responsibility for

  an outcome between the relevant minister(s), the prime minister, their

  various political advisers, the civil service, and other bodies to which

  decisions may have been delegated? And most pertinently of all, how

  much of the applause – or brickbats – we may feel confident enough, at

  

  

   

  this early stage, to apportion among the politicians in charge, can we pass

  to Tony Blair, as opposed to Gordon Brown?

  The macro-economic record

  We should begin with the evidence. The decade from May 1997 has seen

  ten years of continuous and reasonably steady economic growth.

  Unemployment has mostly edged downwards, to levels far below those

  seen in the previous twenty years. Inflation has been modest and steady,

  far lower and less turbulent than in the 1970s or 1980s. Interest rates have

  generally fallen, whether real or nominal, long or short. The stock market

  has trended up (although with some sharp swings). Sterling has climbed

  relative to most of the world’s currencies, above all the US dollar and the

  continental currencies that metamorphosed into the euro. Most of

  Britain’s income groups have witnessed large rises in living standards.

  Except at the edges of the distribution, most of these ten years saw

  declines in inequality and poverty by most definitions. Private consumption spending has been particularly robust.

  This summary of the evidence is distinctly positive. But it needs to be

  seen in perspective. For most variables of interest, the contrast with

  Britain’s experience in the quarter-century to 1997 is especially impressive. But the comparison with the 1950s and 1960s, which the Blair years

  so resemble in many respects, is less so. Those earlier decades displayed

  somewhat faster than average inflation but markedly lower average

  unemployment than the Blair decade. And the ‘bad’ years 1972–97

  present a very uneven picture, with a much stronger performance in most

  respects towards the end than earlier on. The five years 1992–7 are very

  much more like the Blair years than what preceded them; and as we shall

  see later, this may well be no accident.

  Furthermore, one important economic variable, perhaps the most

  important of all, registered barely any change at all after 1997. This is the

  trend rate of economic growth. The trend in real gross domestic product

  per head has remained almost constant since the late 1940s in the UK. It

  has remained rock solid at about 2.4% per year.1 And to complicate

  matters further, there are several other leading countries that displayed

  the same combination of steadier growth and flat (or gently decelerating)

  inflation and unemployment, as Britain.

  11 See W. Allen, R. Batley, E. Baroudy, B. Paulson and P. Sinclair, Growth in Britain

  (University of Birmingham, mimeo, 2007).

      

  

  Table 10.1. Growth and inflation in the big six OECD economies

  Annual average

  Annual

  Annual average

  Annual

  growth rate,

  average

  inflation,

  average

  1997–2007

  growth rate,

  1997–2007

  inflation,

  1992–7

  1992–7

  UK

  2.7

  3.1

  1.7

  2.2

  Unweighted

  1.85

  1.74

  1.46

  2.4

  average of

  next five

  France

  2.2

  1.1

  1.7

  1.8

  Germany

  1.5

  1.3

  1.5

  2.3

  Italy

  1.4

  1.3

  2.3

  4.4

  Japan

  1.2

  1.5

  Ϫ0.8

  0.8

  United States

  2.9

  3.5

  2.6

  2.7

  Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook and author’s calculations and forecasts.

  Britain has done very well when compared with the world’s five other

  largest economies. While quite similar in other respects, the United States

  displays a slightly lower trend in real income per head, though faster in

  aggregate; marked rises in inequality on most definitions; and a somewhat more disturbed series for aggregate output. Japan has hardly grown

  since 1991. Its general absence of inflation – and spells of price declines –

  are not seen, by the Japanese or by outsiders, as an achievement. Rather,

  they are taken to be a major weakness that their authorities have sought

  hard to combat. And what of Germany, France and Italy? Each of these

  three has seen substantially slower average growth and much higher

  unemployment in the Blair years.

  Table 10.1 illustrates. Of the big six OECD economies, the United

  States grew fastest from 1997 to 2007, as it had from 1992 to 1997. (Here

  UK economic performance on Blair’s watch, which lasted for two and a

  half parliaments, is contrasted with the previous parliament, 1992–7, and

  with those of other major countries; and inflation is defined as the percentage annual average change in the country’s consumer price index.)

  Britain came second in both periods. Actual growth was a little slower

  under Blair than in the previous quinquennium. But part of this small

  gap results from rounding, and the strong figure for 1992–7 includes a

  cyclical bounce. Britain’s relative growth performance also appears to

  have slipped across the two periods. The UK grew nearly 1.4% per year

  

   

  Table 10.2. Unemployment in the big six OECD economies

  Average

  Change from

  Average

  Change from

  unemployment

  1997 to 2006

  unemployment

  1992 to 1997

  rate, 1997–2006

  rate, 1992–7

  UK

  5.5

  Ϫ1.7

  9.0

  Ϫ2.7
/>   Unweighted

  7.3

  Ϫ1.4

  7.6

  ϩ0.9

  average of

  next 5

  France

  9.7

  Ϫ2.5

  11.2

  ϩ1.6

  Germany

  8.1

  Ϫ0.5

  7.3

  ϩ2.8

  Italy

  9.2

  Ϫ4.5

  10.5

  ϩ2.5

  Japan

  4.6

  ϩ0.7

  2.9

  ϩ1.2

  United States

  4.9

  Ϫ0.3

  6.1

  Ϫ2.6

  Source: as Table 10.1.

  faster than a simple average of the other five from 1992 to 1997. In Blair’s

  decade, that gap dropped to 0.9%. Average annual consumer price inflation also slowed across the two periods, in absolute terms (1.7% against

  2.2%). Japan’s much bigger swing, from inflation to deflation, places UK

  inflation above the average of the rest in Blair’s years, while it had been

  slightly below earlier.

  Table 10.2 presents unemployment figures for these six economies.

  Britain’s moved from a relatively high (but falling) figure in 1992–7 to relatively low, and still falling, under Blair. These excellent performances

  result from the interplay of several factors. One was Brown’s welfare-towork policies.2 Earlier, sterling’s eviction from the European Exchange

  Rate Mechanism (ERM) in September 1992, and the accompanying

  depreciation and monetary policy loosening this permitted, were important in the mid-1990s. Perhaps the greatest influence, though, was the

  lagged impact of the labour market and trade union law reforms enacted

  by Thatcher. It was to Blair’s credit, and Brown’s, that political pressures

  to repeal them were resisted. Had they succumbed, UK unemployment in

  2007 might well have been closer to rates prevailing in France, Germany

  12 Britain’s tax credit schemes expanded greatly in 2003–4, from foundations first laid in

  1972 with the Family Income Supplement. The idea is to top up incomes for working families with low earnings, and not to reward inactivity. Six million families now receive tax

  credits in Britain, so the scale is very large. But so too is the level of error and fraud: nearly

  £2 billion has been officially described as irrecoverable overpayments.

      

  

  and Italy, all of which had generally fought shy of applying Thatcherite

  reforms.

  Many of Europe’s smaller economies, on the other hand, reveal a considerably stronger record. Growth has been much faster in the Baltic

  Republics, Finland, Ireland, Luxembourg, Norway and Spain than in

  Britain, for example. And many witnessed sharper falls in unemployment, with much the same time profile of inflation as in the UK. Other

  advanced countries outside Europe – Australia, Canada, Mexico, New

  Zealand and South Korea, for example – have also grown at not dissimilar

  rates to Britain’s in this period, and with broadly similar (or better)

  records of inflation and/or unemployment. And Britain’s share of world

  GDP, measured at current exchange rates, fell in the Blair years (as it

  seems to have done in every decade since the mid-Victorian era). This

  was mainly because of the exceptionally rapid growth of most Asian

  economies, especially China and India. Partly because of these countries’

  growing weight in the world aggregate, the long-term slide in the UK

  share of world output might actually have gathered pace on Blair’s watch.

  Some slide is really inevitable: over the long haul, all else being equal,

  richer countries tend to grow significantly more slowly than poorer

  ones.3

  So much for longer-run averages. What of the short-run chronometry

  of the Blair decade? These ten years display no periods of GDP decline, in

  marked contrast to the previous quarter-century of UK data. There had

  been serious recessions in 1973–5, 1979–82 and 1990–2, but not even

  mild ones in 1997–2007. No ‘boom and bust’, agreed; but there was

  unmistakably some undulation in growth. So Britain’s business cycle had

  been squashed. But not abolished. It was in fact really quite like what it

  had been in the 1950s and 1960s, if more muted. Annual growth peaked

  at about 4% in 2000 and 2004, slipping to 2% or less in early 2002 and

  mid-2005. Mild business cycle peaks (points where growth returns to

  trend from above) can be identified in 1997–8, 2001 and 2005. At around

  four years, the interval between the peaks is close to the fifty-four-month

  periodicity detectable for 1951–73. The downswing from 2000 to 2002–3

  is the sharpest cyclical phenomenon in the Blair decade. But it coincides

  with, and doubtless betrays influence from, very much more pronounced

  downswings in the GDP series in the United States, in world trade, and,

  13 This ‘catch-up’ phenomenon is strongly attested in most cases. See G. Doppelhofer, R.

  Miller and X. Sala-i-Martin, ‘Determinants of Long-Term Growth: A Bayesian Averaging

  of Classical Estimates (Bace) Approach’, American Economic Review, 94, 2004: 813–35, for

  a recent study that shows this (and much else).

  

   

  above all, in each of the world’s principal stock markets; and it must have

  been aggravated by the shock of the World Trade Center atrocity.

  The verdict on this broadly satisfactory record is certainly positive.

  Some credit for this must certainly go to Brown, and some, less directly,

  also to Blair. The main achievement of the Blair–Brown partnership was

  perhaps to have retained key features of Thatcher’s reforms (particularly

  lower marginal income tax rates and restrictions on the rights of trades

  unions) that allowed the macro-economic record to blossom. And the

  fact that inequalities and poverty have tended to decline somewhat on

  many definitions (although not all, nor consistently across the decade),

  and not to worsen as they quite often tended to under Thatcher, will

  partly reflect the impact of Brown’s measures to provide more support

  for low-income families in work.

  The euro

  There are few issues of economic policy where we know Blair’s views

  differed sharply from his Chancellor’s. On many they appear largely or

  fully agreed: the need to avoid any increase in the top rate of income tax

  or the standard rate of value added tax; the virtues of the private finance

  initiative; the early acceptance of tight limits on public spending, and its

  spectacular later relaxation on health expenditure; the sedulous courting

  of business; the distancing from Labour’s traditional allies and founders,

  the trades unions. But on one they differed sharply. This was the issue of

  whether the UK should adopt the euro.

  It will have been Blair’s hope, early on in his premiership, that Britain

  would be able, at least at some point, to join Germany, France and her

  other main European Union partners in the world’s first great currency

  merger. But for Brown – who in the 1980s had been if anything less

  Eurosceptic than Blair – that decision wa
s a Treasury-reserved domain.

  The issue was kicked into touch during the first Blair parliament. ‘We

  conclude that the determining factor as to whether Britain joins a single

  currency is the national economic interest, and whether the economic

  case for doing so is clear and unambiguous’, Brown told the House

  of Commons on 27 October 1997.4 The Chancellor devised, and

  announced, five tests,5 all related to aspects of potential benefit or harm

  14 House of Commons Debates, cc. 583–4.

  15 These concerned whether the UK had achieved convergence with Europe; whether it was

  flexible enough to adapt to the change; how UK investment would be affected; the impact on

  the UK’s financial services sector; and the prospects for employment and growth in Britain.

      

  

  to Britain that euro adoption might entail. On the basis of the answers to

  these, to be illuminated by detailed research conducted within and by the

  Treasury, and which the Treasury would publish, Gordon Brown would

  make a recommendation during a second Blair government to the

  cabinet and parliament. A positive recommendation by Brown would

  trigger votes in cabinet, then in parliament, and finally a national referendum. At any point in the chain, a negative one would bury the issue, at

  least for a while.

  Arguments in favour of euro adoption by Britain would include

  several points. There would be some saving of her real resources devoted

  to exchanging sterling and other euro-legacy or euro currencies. There

  could well be a stimulus to trade6 with euro partners. And there would be

  an elimination of exchange rate uncertainties associated with that trade.

  (Given transactions costs, maintaining separate currencies is rather like

  imposing a tax on trade with other countries, but an especially silly tax,

  which, unlike tariffs on imports, does not even have the merit of raising

  any appreciable revenue for government.)

  Potential net welfare gains might come from heightened competition

  in UK markets, as price comparisons between home and EU partner

  firms’ products became less opaque. Gaps between interest rates facing

  lenders and borrowers might narrow, as Britain’s financial markets

  became more liquid. Each of the above might raise the UK’s long-term

  growth rate, possibly even indefinitely.7 There could also be savings in

  foreign exchange reserves and some consequent gain in net foreign

  investment income; and opportunities to reap economies of scale in

 

‹ Prev