Book Read Free

BLAIR’S BRITAIN, 1997–2007

Page 32

by ANTHONY SELDON (edt)


  central banking, and possibly to improve monetary policy processes and

  decisions.

  There are also counter-arguments. Unifying currencies across some,

  but not all countries, will divert trade, very probably wastefully, from

  excluded countries. Exchange rate uncertainties can often be hedged

  against at very modest marginal cost. Your country’s optimum inflation

  16 Some influential indirect evidence supporting this claim includes J. McCallum, ‘National

  Borders Matter: Canada–US Regional Trade Patterns’, American Economic Review, 85,

  1995: 615–23 and A. Rose, ‘One Money, One Market: Estimating the Effect of Common

  Currencies on Trade, Economic Policy, 30, 2000: 7–45.

  17 This would indeed happen in any number of endogenous growth models. See R. E. Lucas,

  ‘Supply Side Economics: An Analytical Review’, Oxford Economic Papers, 42, 1990:

  293–316; P. Romer, ‘Endogenous Technological Change’, Journal of Political Economy, 98,

  1990: S71–102; and P. Aghion and P. Howitt, Endogenous Growth Theory (Cambridge,

  MA: MIT Press, 1998).

  

   

  trend may differ from your monetary union partners’. Asymmetric

  shocks (which have quite different impacts on you and your union partners) must mean that both you, and they, are constrained to follow a

  second-best, common reaction. ‘One size fits all’ probably implies a

  perfect fit for no one. Currency union requires you to surrender the

  option to set interest rates independently, and the option to enact or

  permit changes in your exchange rate. Those two options may have far

  from negligible domestic value.8

  Furthermore, in Britain’s case, there were the luckless dummy runs.

  Sterling joined the ‘snake-in-the-tunnel’ in 1972. Later, in October 1990,

  it entered the ERM. But both of these commitments – however unfortunately timed – were to prove unsustainable. Further possible complications include: wrangles about how to fix entry exchange rates for legacy

  currencies (the partners will have conflicting interests here, and there is

  no easy or agreed way of quantifying a ‘fundamental equilibrium’

  exchange rate9); how to make a supranational central bank democratically accountable; how to ensure that national fiscal policies do not

  undermine the common currency, in the way that, for example, spending

  and deficits of Argentina’s provincial authorities helped to destroy the

  country’s currency board in 2001–2;10 and seignorage allocation disputes.

  From 1997 to 2003, the government’s official position was ‘prepare and

  decide’. Despite its hint of activity and resolve, only a skilled semiologist

  could discern much real difference between this phrase and the Major

  government’s policy of ‘wait and see’. Public opinion on the issue bobbed

  up and down, but showed a consistently negative majority (and no

  overall trend). May 1998 saw it at its smallest in the MORI opinion poll –

  34% in favour, and 48% against. There was a record majority against in

  November 2000 (18% in favour, 71% against). Typically there were about

  18 With its independent currency, France could devalue its way out of the wage hikes, agreed

  between (then) premier Pompidou and trade union leaders, that ended its national strike

  in 1968. But if events ever repeated themselves under the euro, France would be doomed

  to suffer a haemorrhage of its external competitiveness and jobs.

  19 As explored recently, for example, by R. Driver and P. Westaway, ‘Concepts of Equilibrium

  Exchange Rates’, in R. Driver, P. Sinclair and C. Thoenissen (eds.), Exchange Rates, Capital

  Flows and Policy (London: Routledge, 2005).

  10 See A. Powell, ‘The Argentine Crisis: Bad Luck, Bad Management, Bad Policies, Bad

  Advice’, Brookings Trade Forum (Washington DC: Brookings Institution Press, 2003); and

  F. S. Mishkin, The Next Great Globalization: How Disadvantaged Countries Can Harness

  their Financial Systems to Get Rich (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2006) for

  more on this.

      

  

  twice as many against as in favour throughout the period from 1992 to

  2003. Opposition was on the whole rather stronger among women,

  over thirty-fives, lower-income groups and those inclined to vote

  Conservative. The Conservative Party made its hostility to abandoning

  sterling a central plank in its 2001 general election campaign, and subsequently attributed its drubbing to undue emphasis on the issue.

  Nonetheless, the fact that winning a referendum on euro entry looked a

  hopeless prospect was clearly critical in reconciling Blair to staying out, at

  least for a while. It may also have helped to strengthen Brown’s doubts

  about the wisdom of entry.

  In June 2003, Brown announced his verdict to the House of Commons:

  ‘A clear and unambiguous case for UK membership of the EMU has not

  at the present time been made and a decision to join now would not be in

  the national economic interest.’ The accompanying Treasury document11

  stated that ‘we cannot . . . conclude that there is sustainable and durable

  convergence or sufficient flexibility to cope with any potential difficulties

  within the euro area’. On a more positive note, Brown did announce that

  the country’s inflation target (2.5% per year increase in the Retail Price

  Index, definition RPIX) would switch to one based on the Consumer

  Price Index (which was easier to compare with the ‘harmonized index of

  consumer prices’ watched by European Central Bank). He also declared

  that steps would be taken to modify Britain’s housing and mortgage

  markets, in line with the recommendations of the Barker12 and Miles13

  reports that he had commissioned.

  Was Brown right to say no (or not yet) to the euro? It is interesting to

  speculate on what would have happened had (a) sterling joined at the

  inception (1999, with notes and coins debuting in 2002), or (b) Brown

  announced that his tests had been met, and (improbably) that ratification

  11 It was buttressed by an eighteen-volume research document, HM Treasury, ‘UK

  Membership of the Single Currency: EMU Studies’, 2003, www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/documents/international_issues/the_euro/assessment/studies.

  12 K. Barker, Delivering Stability: Securing Our Future Housing Needs, Final Report (London:

  HMSO, 2004). House prices were increasing strongly in the UK – and also in some euro

  area economies with faster growth, such as Ireland and Spain – to much larger multiples of

  income than in France, Germany and Italy, raising concerns about overall monetary

  stability in the short run and financial stability in the longer run.

  13 D. Miles, The UK Mortgage Market: Taking a Longer-Term View, Final Report and

  Recommendations (London: HMSO, 2004). Unlike much of the rest of the EU, Britain’s

  mortgages were typically at variable interest rates, not rates fixed for several years. This

  raised worries that the transmission mechanism of monetary policy could be more violent

  in Britain, a special concern if interest rates were to be set with reference to euro-areawide, rather than UK, economic conditions.

  

  �
� 

  by parliament and people been followed swiftly in 2004. In either case,

  adding UK data to the aggregate euro area statistics would probably have

  led the ECB into a slightly more hawkish stance for the time profile of its

  policy rate. This is because UK unemployment, unlike Germany’s,

  France’s and Italy’s, has been low by historical standards. But, for the same

  reason, the policy rate would surely have been set at lower rates than the

  UK’s.

  There is a curious (and in the author’s view, needlessly restrictive)

  convention that policy rate changes are normally limited to twenty-five

  basis points (one quarter of one per cent) or multiples thereof. Partly

  because of this, but principally because the UK would have formed

  barely one-sixth of the hypothetically enlarged euro area (EA+, call it),

  our counterfactual thought experiment would have EA+ rates set very

  much closer to the ECB’s than the Bank of England’s actual rates. This

  suggests that euro participation could actually have served to overcook

  the UK’s already relatively overheated economy. EA+ rates would also, to

  some degree, have deepened the doldrums for the three large euro area

  economies: any rise in interest rates would have intensified their problems of sluggishness in production, investment and employment

  growth. Lower policy rates would probably also have inflamed the UK

  housing market, either, as in Ireland, by pushing up prices strongly in

  2000–2 when they were still rather quiet (had the UK joined early on), or

  (with entry in 2004) by intensifying the 2003–6 giddy house price boom.

  And an enlarged euro would probably have seen its external value fall less

  than it did in 2000, and recover more slowly in 2004–6. Although the

  UK’s mild 2000–3 downswing could have been softened somewhat by

  the consequences of early euro entry, the major effects would, on

  balance, probably have been to destabilise GDP (and inflation) in the UK

  and also in the euro area core. The first technical, scholarly attempt to

  gauge the effects of euro entry-at-inception on the UK and Sweden

  reaches not dissimilar conclusions.14 Future research may of course

  point to a different conclusion. Or we might see some evidence of sharp

  increases in intra-euro area trade and in growth rates that advocates of

  the euro project once prophesied.15 But there is precious little evidence

  of this to date.

  14 H. Pesaran, V. Smith and R. Smith, ‘What if the UK or Sweden Had Joined the Euro in

  1999? An Empirical Evaluation Using a Global VAR’, International Journal of Finance and

  Economics, 12, 2007: 55–87.

  15 See, for example, M. Emerson, D. Gros and A. Italiener, One Market, One Money (Oxford:

  Oxford University Press, 1992).

      

  

  Furthermore, there have been asymmetric shocks that have affected

  EU countries in different ways. Instances include the big 2004–6 jump in

  oil prices (relatively bullish for sterling), major differences in immigration patterns, and sharp increases in Chinese exports (neutral to favourable for some EU countries, but especially damaging for Italy, given its

  greater similarity in export patterns). And perhaps the biggest argument

  for keeping sterling out of the euro area for a while was another asymmetry. Postponing entry would allow experts to quantify actual effects and

  see how things worked out (‘the value of waiting’). Importantly it would

  also preserve options. Entry, an all but irreversible commitment, could

  only close them.

  Other financial and monetary issues

  If the Blair–Brown economic policy record is crowned by its essentially

  negative – and judicious – decision to stand aside from the euro area, there

  are some positive radical changes that it introduced as well. Foremost

  here were granting operational independence to the Bank of England,

  and the creation of the Financial Services Authority to combine the

  supervising roles of numerous bodies, the Bank included. Both changes

  were announced in early May 1997, in the first days of Blair’s government.

  They had been prefigured in some earlier Labour policy pronouncements. But the Bank independence decision astonished observers with

  the speed and manner of its execution. The key idea is that politicians are

  inherently short-sighted – fixated by impending elections – and therefore

  tempted to do things that bring short-term gain at long-term cost.

  Among these, Barro and Gordon argued,16 were policy decisions that

  affected inflation. An unexpected rise in inflation would bring extra

  output, profits and jobs for a while; so politicians that declared a promise

  to keep inflation low, the right policy for the long run, would soon misbehave and lose credibility. The output gains would be fleeting, but the

  extra inflation would do harm. Better, therefore, to pass monetary policy

  decisions to a ‘conservative’ central banker who made low inflation his

  sole priority17 – or set the central bank a widely published, transparent,

  low inflation commitment (a ‘target’) and let it get on with it, with no

  political interference. Perhaps it was no accident that the astonishingly

  16 R. Barro and D. Gordon, ‘Rules, Discretion and Reputation in a Model of Monetary

  Policy’, Journal of Monetary Economics, 12, 1983: 101–21.

  17 K. Rogoff, ‘The Optimal Degree of Commitment to an Intermediate Monetary Target’,

  Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100, 1985: 1169–89.

  

   

  rapid inflation rates in all the world’s democracies during the second half

  of the twentieth century – so much higher than the approximately zero

  rates seen in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries – owed much to

  lagged effects of franchise extensions, and the Keynesian revolution that

  encouraged politicians to seize the levers of monetary policy and use

  them to try to defend and create jobs.

  Brown’s move was indeed a radical departure. It accorded with the

  grain of the times, and followed most of the best recent academic thinking on the issue. It was welcomed by the financial markets, which

  promptly lowered nominal interest rates on longer-term (sterlingdenominated) UK government debt sharply, demonstrating a belief that

  British inflation would be substantially lower as a result. But just how

  novel was it? In some ways, the new arrangements represented a step back

  to the years before 1939, or 1914, when policy interest rate decisions were

  taken by the Governor of the Bank of England, not the Chancellor. In

  others, it was a logical extension of Norman Lamont’s decision in 1992 to

  replace the broken anchor of British monetary policy – the link to the

  German Mark – with a new monetary framework, inflation-targeting,

  which New Zealand had initiated barely three years before. And before

  that Nigel Lawson had wanted to grant the Bank operational independence. The fact that Lawson could not tells us how subordinate most

  Chancellors are, in some key issues, to 10 Downing Street. But where

  Thatcher forbade, Blair was to delegate, at least to the Chancellor if not to
<
br />   other ministerial colleagues. Perhaps Blair just preferred to involve

  himself in foreign affairs, in education, in health, in Ulster, and saw that

  his time was limited and his talents and interests better confined to those

  spheres. Perhaps he and Brown agreed from the start that Brown should

  have an untrammelled say in all matters economic. And perhaps Blair

  recalled how Thatcher never really recovered from Lawson’s angry resignation, and determined not to repeat that error. There is probably some

  truth in all three of these statements.

  In the new system, a Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) would meet

  at the Bank each month to set the UK’s short-term policy rate,18 by

  majority vote. The MPC consisted of the Governor and two Deputy

  Governors of the Bank (all crown appointees on renewable five-year

  terms), two other Bank officials, and four external members, chosen by

  the Chancellor, serving three-year renewable terms. A tenth non-voting

  member would be a Treasury official. So the sense in which the Bank

  18 Known as Bank Rate from 2006.

      

  

  of England gained independence in 1997 was strongly nuanced.

  Furthermore, it lacked goal independence. The MPC would be charged

  by the Chancellor with aiming at a specific number for the rate of inflation (2.5% RPIX, later changed to 2% CPI).19 Other objectives, such as

  sustaining employment and growth, were to be secondary to that. If inflation over a year strayed by more than 1% from the target, the Governor

  would write an open letter to the Chancellor explaining why the target

  had been missed, and what action might be taken to attain it later. In the

  ten years of Blair’s premiership, coterminous with the first ten years of the

  MPC, just one letter had to be written, right at the end. Until March 2007,

  annual inflation was never more than 1% off target. The upper limit was

  touched in January 2007, then breached two months later, largely as a

  result of oil price movements.

  You must have a nominal anchor. To see that, look at the huge jump in

  Britain’s annual inflation rate, to 26% in 1975, which followed her pilotless exit from the snake-in-the-tunnel in 1972. But which? Monetary

  targets – but for which monetary aggregate, and why an indirect one

 

‹ Prev